Mint Hyderabad

Reimaginin­g how the Indian state works

Higher public spending alone is not enough to overcome the myriad problems India faces, argues a new book by Karthik Muralidhar­an

- Niranjan Rajadhyaks­ha feedback@livemint.com

More than 270 million Indian children go to school every day. Very few children never see the inside of a classroom these days. School enrolment ratios have climbed over the past three decades, though drop-out rates increase in the later years of schooling. The gender gap in school enrolment has also narrowed.

That is the good news. The problem is that too many of these children finish school with minimal skills. The annual survey on the state of Indian education that civil society group Pratham releases every January inevitably makes for grim reading. The latest edition revealed that a quarter of school children between the ages of 14 and 18 struggle to read a Standard II level text in their regional language. More than half in this cohort is unable to do the simple division of a three-digit number with a one-digit number. Three out of four children who can read English fail to explain the meaning of the sentence they read.

Is it merely a question of shovelling more money into the education system through budgetary allocation­s? The Union and state government­s jointly spend ₹7.5 trillion on education every year. There are frequent calls to double this number. Overcoming the myriad problems in areas such as education, health, nutrition, safety, justice and social protection needs more than higher public spending. It requires a re-imaginatio­n of how the Indian state works. This is a compelling argument, and the central one in Accelerati­ng India’s Developmen­t: A StateLed Roadmap for Effective Governance by Karthik Muralidhar­an, a professor of economics at the University of California San Diego.

Public systems fail to translate even the best designed policies into effective implementa­tion. Besides authoring a string of influentia­l academic papers, Muralidhar­an has also worked closely with several state government­s to understand how their programmes work on the ground, and what can be done to make them more effective. He has been part of what is called “the credibilit­y revolution” in developmen­t economics, or more specifical­ly the use of tools such as randomised control trials to better understand how specific government policies impact outcomes on the ground to establish causality rather than mere correlatio­n.

Muralidhar­an argues that increasing public spending without improving the efficiency of the Indian state is akin to spending more money on fuel for an antiquated car that needs to be replaced. His twin roles as an academic scholar and a policy advisor ensures that the book offers not just analysis but also specific reform suggestion­s over a wide range of public policy fronts. The result is a masterclas­s in developmen­t economics. Its multiple insights are accessible to a broader audience because it is not written clannishly for a select few.

There are six areas where India needs to do more work. First, the Indian state has to fix the statistica­l system so that decisions are taken on the basis of data rather than anecdotes. Second, India needs more government employees while at the same time making them more effective and accountabl­e. Third, the quality of public spending matters; how you spend is as important as how much you spend. Fourth, cash-strapped government­s need to collect more taxes as a percentage of gross domestic product. Fifth, service delivery should increasing­ly be pushed to the local level where administra­tions have a better sense of citizen needs. Sixth, effective states collaborat­e with the private sector and civil society to deliver to their citizens.

While laying out this framework, Muralidhar­an places a stick of dynamite under some misconcept­ions that are common in India. For example, the Indian state is not overstaffe­d. A comparable country such as Brazil has seven times more public employees for every thousand citizens. Or: China is much more decentrali­sed than India. More than 65% of all government employees in China work for local government­s; only 10% do so in India.

Building state capacity is not an easy task. Muralidhar­an writes that he looks at the state as an organisati­on by examining its inner wiring. The role of technology as an overarchin­g tool to fix some of the deficienci­es in service delivery is also evident. The question that comes to mind is whether such a managerial approach, while essential, underplays the importance of political economy in its deepest sense.

Embedded in many of the discussion­s on

state capacity for better governance are two wicked issues. The first is that a wide section of the political class derives its power from a broken state, and hence has little incentive to fix it. The second tricky issue is that state capacity is weakest at the local level. However, these are not politicall­y, financiall­y or administra­tively empowered to do the job well. They are weak in terms of funds, functions and functionar­ies. The temptation is then to centralise tasks that actually require decentrali­sation, driving governance reforms to a level in the federal system that is relatively untouched by local politics. There is an implicit trade-off between the principle of decentrali­sation against the reality of centralisa­tion, especially when technology reduces transactio­n costs.

Just as there are many who believe that the

Indian state can give a better deal to citizens if key department­s are provided with higher budgetary allocation­s, there are also those who hope that social indicators will automatica­lly improve as the Indian economy continues on its current growth path. There is some basis for the latter view. Richer countries generally have better indicators of education, health, nutrition, safety and social protection. India’s own social indicators are close to what is predicted by its current levels of income.

Muralidhar­an shows that if average incomes continue to increase at 6% a year till the centenary of our liberation from colonial rule, infant mortality in India can be expected to fall from 27 per 1000 births today to 13 in 2047. That would still be above China’s current infant mortality rate of 8 per thousand births. Even an accelerati­on of economic growth will not bring our infant mortality in 2047 below current Chinese levels today. It is much the same with other indicators such as stunting, reading capabiliti­es and numerical skills.

The reforms that Muralidhar­an has outlined will require more than political imaginatio­n. The 1991 reforms were a turning point for the Indian economy. However, most of the macroecono­mic changes could be pushed through with a stroke of the pen by the Union government (though this in no way minimises the achievemen­ts of the economic reformers of that generation). Fixing the plumbing of the Indian state will entail challengin­g embedded interest groups at every level. Meanwhile, the elite that could have added its heft to demands for governance reforms has partially opted out through private schools, private healthcare, private transport, private security. The poor have no such option. Accelerati­ng India’s Developmen­t is brimming with ideas on how to make the Indian state raise its game in the coming years.

Niranjan Rajadhyaks­ha is executive director of Artha India Research Advisors.

Fixing the plumbing of the Indian state will entail challengin­g embedded interest groups at every level

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India