The Hindu - International

The physics and maths of keeping elections fair and representa­tive

While mathematic­al analysis helps sharpen an algorithm for the election, a physics perspectiv­e can diagnose if it is fairly implemente­d in practice. The science of elections has a long way to go but for millions across the world, the elections of 2024 pro

- M.S. Santhanam Aanjaneya Kumar Ritam Pal

Across the world, elections are a volatile mixture of emotions, aspiration­s, competing ideologies, and sometimes even violence. It might then surprise many that, despite the cacophony, there is science behind the election’s processes

There are about 60 national elections in 2024 involving two billion people, including the biggest of them — the national elections underway in India — and the election to the U.S. presidency. Across the world, elections are a volatile mixture of emotions, aspiration­s, competing ideologies, and sometimes even violence. It might then surprise many that, despite the cacophony, there is science behind the election’s processes.

About 2,500 years ago, the earliest form of elections in ancient Athens was a system that ultimately depended on the candidate’s luck. Among all the suitable candidates, one was randomly chosen. Since the winning criterion was based on random choice, campaignin­g or in—uence couldn’t help the candidate.

Tenth-century Chola inscriptio­ns at Uthirameru­r in Tamil Nadu reveal the practice of choosing village representa­tives through a ‘Kudavolai’ system. The nal choice was made by randomly picking one among the candidates the people had voted for.

The ‘ rst past the post’ system?

Today, social choice theorists and mathematic­ians who study elections call this the approval voting system followed by a random choice. As a means of electing candidates, this process fails to re—ect the will of the people. If this is a —awed process, what would be the right way to elect candidates? Surprising­ly, mathematic­s tells us that there is no simple answer to this question.

The rst-past-the-post (FPTP) system followed in India, the U.S., the U.K., and several other countries has many drawbacks. Critics have pointed out the disproport­ionate diŸerence between the popular vote share and the seat share in many Parliament­s. For example, in the 2015 Delhi Assembly elections, the Aam Aadmi Party received 54% of the popular vote but won 96% of the seats, whereas the Bharatiya Janata Party won 32% and 4%, respective­ly.

Second, winners in the FPTP system often secure far less than 50% of the vote share. No government in India, irrespecti­ve of its strength in the Lok Sabha (i.e. number of seats), has ever surpassed 50% vote share. Since 1918, only once, in 1931 in the U.K., did a government command more than 50%. So by the vote-share metric India and the U.K. were always ruled by “minority” government­s. Expectedly, social choice theorists disfavour the FPTP system, though it continues to nd wide use for its simplicity.

Condorcet and Borda systems

Are there better alternativ­es? Mathematic­al analysis to design better electoral systems dates back to the 13th century in the works of Ramon Llull, a missionary and theologian. His book

Arte Eleccionis, in the Catalan language, gives a detailed algorithm for a two-stage election process for church o§cials. It ensures that the winner, when pitted against each of the other contenders, receives more than 50% votes and is the most preferred candidate. This work was lost for centuries until it was discovered in the late 1980s.

DeToday, Llull’s method is called the Condorcet system after the 18th-century French mathematic­ian Nicolas de Condorcet, who rediscover­ed it in the 1780s. While better than FPTP, the Condorcet system can be di§cult to understand and isn’t used in any national election, not least because its mechanism allows participan­ts to prevent the election of a particular candidate. Some smaller organisati­ons use it to elect their leaders and board members, however.

The Borda electoral process, proposed by French mathematic­ian Jean-Charles de Borda in 1784 — but rst described by the 15th-century German astronomer Nicolas of Cusa — is a rank-based voting system (RVS) similar to the points table in sporting tournament­s like the Indian Premier League.

It allows voters to rank each candidate on the ballot paper, and through a process of vote redistribu­tion, the winner is guaranteed to have at least 50% of the vote.

Redistribu­tion of votes can take several forms; the most common is to add the second and even third preference votes until one of the candidates crosses 50% vote share.

Are there problems with RVS?

The President of India is elected with the RVS system. In 1969, none of the 15 presidenti­al candidates secured 50% of the rst-preference votes. After adding second preference votes, V.V. Giri (who had 48% rst preference votes) reached 50.8% and was declared the winner, defeating Neelam Sanjeeva Reddy.

Like Condorcet, the original Borda method is complex and challengin­g to implement in large elections such as those in India.

In 1951, the American economist and Nobel laureate Kenneth Arrow proved that RVS can con—ict with certain fairness criteria required of elections. This doesn’t imply such systems are unfair, even if occasional­ly the most popular candidate may fail to get elected.

Consider an RVS election with three candidates, A, B, and C, with nine voters ranking their preference­s.

The results can read thus: four voters prefer B over C, and prefer A over both B and C. This informatio­n can be represente­d as A > B > C (4). Similarly, other voters may yield diŸerent combinatio­ns: B > C > A (3) and C > A > B (2). The distributi­on indicates A received the maximum number of rst preference votes and C the least. Suppose B withdraws from the election. In a fair election, we should expect the result to remain unaŸected — but this isn’t the case with RVS.

Here, with the same vote distributi­on, the result will now read A > C (4 votes) and C > A (5 votes). So C has the most rst preference votes now and wins. Arrow’s theorem asserts that such outcomes are unavoidabl­e in an RVS election.

How can maths, physics help?

Ironically, while the cold rigour of mathematic­s sheds light on the inherently boisterous election processes, more grounded physics approaches draw on this lack of order to seek universal patterns irrespecti­ve of electoral systems. This is not unusual in physics.For example, inside a balloon, billions of molecules, moving randomly and bumping against one another, conspire together to produce a constant pressure that keeps the balloon puŸed up.

This is the central lesson of statistica­l physics: order can emerge at the large scale even if dominated by disorder at smaller scales. Two decades of election data analysis has revealed emergent patterns in the form of the distributi­ons of quantities that matter to an electoral process. Despite the super cial chaos surroundin­g the elections, these patterns are robust and independen­t of details, such as where elections were held, the voting paradigm or the cultural context.

Axiomatica­lly, the absence of such order would suggest that elections are/were not fair and could be used to diagnose and —ag electoral malpractic­es.

In short, while mathematic­al analysis helps sharpen an algorithm for the election process, a physics perspectiv­e serves to diagnose if the algorithm is fairly implemente­d in practice. The science of elections has a long way to go, but for millions of people across the world, the elections of 2024 provide hope that the future is in their hands.

(M.S. Santhanam is a professor of physics, and Aanjaneya Kumar and Ritam Pal are doctoral students, all at the Indian Institute of Science Education and

Research, Pune.)

 ?? REUTERS ?? The first-past-the-post system followed in India, the U.S., the U.K., and several other countries has many drawbacks.
REUTERS The first-past-the-post system followed in India, the U.S., the U.K., and several other countries has many drawbacks.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India