Jamaica Gleaner

Outlaw cryptocurr­encies now

- Willem H. Buiter is a visiting professor of internatio­nal and public affairs at Columbia University. www.project-syndicate.org

THE PRICE of bitcoin has undergone yet another wild gyration, rising from US$41,030 on September 29, 2021, to US$69,000 on November 10, 2021, before falling back to US$35,075 on January 23.

That is its second-largest decline in absolute value, though it has suffered larger declines in percentage terms, such as between December 15, 2017, and December 14, 2018, when it fell by 83.8 per cent.

More broadly, the cryptocurr­ency market – comprising some 12,278 coins – was estimated to be worth US$3.3 trillion on November 8, 2021, before plummeting to US$1.75 trillion as of January 30.

A private digital asset based on a distribute­d ledger technology known as blockchain, bitcoin is used as a decentrali­sed digital currency – a peer-to-peer electronic cash system. With no intrinsic value, its market valuation, in terms of US dollars, is nothing more than a bubble.

If you got in early and ‘held on for dear life’ – the price of bitcoin was US$327 on November 20, 2015 – you would be looking at a capital gain of 11,521.5 per cent as of January 30. But, although bitcoin could be worth US$200,000 by the end of this month, it also could be worth nothing. There is no anchor.

If, through a random convergenc­e of random factors, bitcoin achieves a positive valuation at some point in time, subsequent valuations presumably must be driven by the arbitrage condition requiring that risk-adjusted returns on different assets be equal. And because zero is always a possible valuation for bitcoin, we can expect wild swings in its price.

True, the same applies to the valuation of central bank-issued fiat money. Though its use in paying taxes and its status as legal tender give it a leg up on cryptocurr­encies, economics falls short when it comes to determinin­g the market value of this central bank liability. Lacking intrinsic value, it is freely convertibl­e only into itself. And though one can postulate a wellbehave­d demand function for real money balances, this amounts to assuming the problem away.

Nor does it help to assume, instead, that the real stock of central bank fiat money yields unspecifie­d productive services or mysterious uses for households. The best economics has come up with is the assumption that efficient barter is impossible, and that fiat money is therefore necessary to execute essential transactio­ns, like consumer purchases.

But even if we could squeeze a meaningful demand for real money balances out of our intrinsica­lly valueless fiat money universe, determinin­g the price of money – the inverse of the general price level of goods and services – would remain problemati­c, because, in a world of flexible prices, there will always be multiple equilibria.

For example, assume the nominal money stock – the total supply of currency in the economy – and every other relevant factor is kept constant. Even under these simplified conditions, there is nothing to pin down the initial value of the price level.

There is always an equilibriu­m with a zero price of money, implying an infinite general price level. Moreover, for different initial conditions, there may be rational inflationa­ry bubbles or deflationa­ry bubbles, limit cycles, or chaotic behaviour. There is also a unique ‘fundamenta­l’ equilibriu­m in which the price of money is held to be positive and constant. Finally, random transition­s between different equilibria can also be equilibria in themselves. With irrational behaviour and inefficien­t markets, the scope for market turmoil increases.

Neoclassic­al economics asserts that the ‘fundamenta­l’ equilibriu­m prevails, whereas Keynesian economics avoids the multiple-equilibria conundrum by insisting that the general price level is not a flexible asset price driven by arbitrage. Instead, it is sticky or rigid.

History assigns an initial value to the general price level, which is then updated with a dynamic inflation equation like the Phillips curve, which asserts a stable, inverse relationsh­ip between inflation and unemployme­nt. That approach is not great, but I can live with it.

When central bank-issued fiat currency has value, so, too, do private assets that are confidentl­y expected to be convertibl­e into central bank money on demand and at a fixed price – like commercial bank deposits. And government deposit insurance boosts that confidence even when most assets held by banks are illiquid.

By contrast, stablecoin­s – digital currencies that are supposedly convertibl­e into dollars on demand at a fixed price – are effectivel­y deposits without the insurance. When and where they are accepted, they can facilitate digital payments. But they are risky, even if the assets held against them have intrinsic value.

And, if the proceeds from a stablecoin issuance are invested in intrinsica­lly valueless crypto assets, that stablecoin’s stability is bound to be challenged by the markets.

The current popularity of spectacula­rly risky, intrinsica­lly worthless cryptocurr­encies is hard to fathom, and buyers’ faith in a blockchain’s ability to maintain an unalterabl­e record of transactio­ns may soon be tested by the arrival of quantum computing, creating even more risks. Moreover, the amount of energy consumed by proof-of-work distribute­d ledgers – like bitcoin’s blockchain – becomes more massive with every transactio­n, making the case for proper carbon pricing or, failing that, a tax on cryptocurr­ency mining.

The anonymity afforded to cryptocurr­ency holders raises serious concerns about illegal uses of funds, including tax evasion, money laundering, hiding proceeds from ransomware attacks and other cybercrime­s, and financing of terrorism. The issue has become urgent – and regulation may not be enough.

 ?? ??
 ?? ?? Willem Buiter
GUEST COLUMNIST
Willem Buiter GUEST COLUMNIST

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Jamaica