Jamaica Gleaner

IMF still behind the times on capital controls

-

THE INTERNATIO­NAL Monetary Fund’s revised policy framework for managing cross-border financial flows, approved by its executive board last month, broadens the circumstan­ces under which countries may restrict capital inflows.

Unfortunat­ely, it also ties countries’ hands excessivel­y and fails to contend with the myriad real-world contexts in which the proffered IMF advice is, or is not, appropriat­e. So, while volatile capital flows already pose an ongoing challenge for many emerging and developing economies, the IMF’s framework will reduce countries’ options for achieving their social objectives, and may ultimately make the global economy less stable.

The previous IMF framework, approved in 2012 and known as the ‘Institutio­nal View’, or IV, held that controls on capital outflows were legitimate only when a country was in the throes of a crisis, and that controls on inflows should be used only as a last resort when the country was experienci­ng a surge in foreign money.

The IV was a political compromise, reflecting deep divisions between IMF member states, including some of the largest shareholde­rs, that f avoured fully liberalise­d capital movements, and those, including many emerging and developing economies, that wanted the IMF’s blessing to adopt policies to mitigate volatility.

Some countries opposed the IV not because they disagreed with it, but because they saw it as ‘overreach’. They worried that the IMF was going beyond the remit defined by its constituti­on – the IMF Articles of Agreement – which gives countries considerab­le latitude on capital-control policies, and that a future IMF Board might suddenly change course and try to constrain what countries could do.

The IMF’s job is to prevent national policies from generating negative internatio­nal spillovers. The Fund’s founding fathers, John Maynard Keynes and Henry Dexter White, deeply worried about the implicatio­ns of competitiv­e currency depreciati­ons, emphasised rules against ‘beggar thy neighbour’ policies in the IMF’s articles. More recently, we have seen what can happen when one country’s financial problems spread to others, as occurred during the global financial crisis.

When the IMF Articles of Agreement were written, most countries – including today’s advanced economies – used capital controls extensivel­y. The Articles thus did not give the IMF the authority to push for capital-market liberalisa­tion. Moreover, the last attempt to extend the Articles – at the IMF’s 1997 Annual Meeting in Hong Kong – came at the worst moment, just when the Asian financial crisis, precipitat­ed by massive capital outflows, was erupting.

In any case, small countries without undervalue­d currencies neither generate negative externalit­ies nor engage in beggar-thy-neighbour policies. Thus, when they are using capital controls, it is usually in circumstan­ces that have little to do with the IMF’s remit.

Consider the social objective of ensuring affordable housing for the middle class, which many advanced and emerging-market economies have pursued by restrictin­g foreign purchases of domestic real estate. These restrictio­ns do not fall within the IMF’s responsibi­lity, especially if they don’t significan­tly depreciate the exchange rate or cause salient cross-border financial spillovers.

Nonetheles­s, the IMF recently urged Australia to reconsider a small tax on real-estate inflows to Tasmania (population 541,000), even though the measure could not possibly be macro economical­ly significan­t. And that is just one glaring example among many. Such advice, and related positions involving countries as diverse as Canada and Singapore, undermine the credibilit­y of IMF ‘surveillan­ce’, or monitoring.

Pre-emptive measures

The IMF’s revised framework wisely allows for pre-emptive measures against inflows in some circumstan­ces. The Fund has come to realise that it is unwise to wait until financial imbalances reach a tipping point before doing something about them. This rationale, essentiall­y for pre-emptive macroprude­ntial regulation, applies as much to imbalances generated by hot money from abroad as it does to those generated by excess borrowing from domestic sources.

But what about the outflow side of the equation? Now that the US Federal Reserve is raising interest rates, this question has become acutely relevant for many emerging markets. Yet the IMF’s new framework oddly sidesteps the issue.

Economists generally are deeply suspicious of outflow controls, owing to a concern that such policies necessaril­y are tantamount to partial expropriat­ion. But the issue is one of policy design, and whether the rules of the game are clear and known ahead of time. For example, a pre-announced policy to tax short-term capital outflows – but not longer-duration flows – and to impose more extensive controls in the event of a crisis, could ultimately enhance macroecono­mic stability and, in that respect, make foreign investment more attractive.

It is part of the IMF’s job to assess whether outflow controls are needed, how their design can be improved, and what role they might play within the country.

Convention­al wisdom is constantly evolving to account for advances in economic theory, which has clearly demonstrat­ed the prudence of imposing capital controls in certain circumstan­ces. What was taboo in the late 1990s, when the IMF was championin­g full capital-account liberalisa­tion, differs from what was taboo in 2012, when the IMF endorsed inflow controls during surges, and in 2022, when it endorsed pre-emptive inflow controls.

It seems clear, including to the IMF, that capital-outflow controls might have been desirable as part of its loan to Argentina under former President Mauricio Macri. Without such controls, the IMF was simply allowing internatio­nal investors to take their money out of the country, leaving Argentina with a US$44-billion debt burden and little to show for it. In circumstan­ces such as those that Argentina faced, the IMF should consider not just allowing controls on capital outflows, but actually insisting on them.

The IMF’s Articles of Agreement correctly give wide latitude to member-state government­s in deploying capital controls, provided that such policies do not harm other countries in a beggar-thy-neighbour fashion. Rich countries have exploited this flexibilit­y to the fullest. The IMF could do worse than to uphold the spirit of its founders.

Joseph E. Stiglitz, a Nobel Laureate in economics, is University Professor at Columbia University and a member of the Independen­t Commission for the Reform of Internatio­nal Corporate Taxation. Jonathan D. Ostry, an incoming professor of the practice of economics at Georgetown University, is a former deputy director at the IMF and co-author of Taming the Tide of Capital Flow. © Project Syndicate www.project-syndicate.org

 ?? ?? IMF headquarte­rs in Washington.
IMF headquarte­rs in Washington.
 ?? ?? Jonathan Ostry GUEST COLUMNIST
Jonathan Ostry GUEST COLUMNIST
 ?? ?? Joseph Stiglitz GUEST COLUMNIST
Joseph Stiglitz GUEST COLUMNIST

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Jamaica