The Japan News by The Yomiuri Shimbun

‘New class’ might set off instabilit­y in China

- TAKENORI INOKI Special to The Yomiuri Shimbun

China, a single-party authoritar­ian state, has realized fast economic growth by fully capitalizi­ng on the vitality of the market economy. In that process, cra y technocrat­s have played a large role, taking advantage of the leniency of the relevant laws to moderately intervene in the country’s private economic sector. Admittedly, it is an irony of history that a socialist state reminds me anew of the harsh reality of a competitiv­e economy — only the ttest will survive. At the same time, however, the force of widening income inequality — the negative side of market economies — has de nitely been operating in China as well, with uneven distributi­on and immobiliza­tion of wealth and income progressin­g unabated.

When I was a student in the mid1960s, university courses on “economic systems” focused primarily on comparison­s between the “ideals” of Soviet-style socialist planned economies and the “realities” of harshly competitiv­e economies. An overwhelmi­ng number of courses served as platforms to passionate­ly tout the former. As a result, more than a few people at Japanese universiti­es dreamed of the rationalit­y of socialist planned economies despite not having any knowledge, direct or indirect, about their realities.

But times have since changed. e Chinese Communist Party has been pushing its way toward encouragin­g enterprise­s to pursue pro ts, a rming the private ownership of manufactur­ing facilities and promoting measures to make not only capital, but also labor and land liquid or transferab­le. Indeed, the Chinese economy has evolved in a way reminiscen­t of the neoliberal economic policies then U.K. Prime Minister Margaret atcher and then U.S. President Ronald Reagan advocated in the 1980s.

IMMOBILE INCOME GAP

According to an academic article which assessed recent changes in income distributi­on in China, income inequality at the household level there has greatly increased both among provinces and between urban and rural areas in the past four decades. As far as the latest decade is concerned, such inequality has stabilized at high levels, meaning that income distributi­on has become

xed in recent years with no signs of equalizati­on.

Furthermor­e, a factor-by-factor analysis of the levels of inequality across China shows a decline in the impact of factors related to urban-rural disparitie­s and interregio­nal inequality. An increase in “capital income” — which derives not from labor but from capital — has been pointed out as a new trend contributi­ng to the escalation of overall inequality in China.

A notable point is that in China, there exists a distinctly negative correlatio­n between the extent of inequality in income distributi­on and that of “income mobility,” which refers to the extent to

which people move up or down the income strata. Put di erently, the income strata tend to become increasing­ly immobile in those areas and times in which inequality increases. So, the socalled Great Gatsby Curve, which shows how inheritabl­e richness and poverty are, is observed in China as evidence that the strati cation of Chinese society, based on asset and income levels, is progressin­g.

In recent years, income growth of male Chinese workers with higher education in their prime has emerged as a major factor for widening income inequality. Wages and salaries for the Chinese elite with higher education have been on the rise thanks to the ongoing privatizat­ion of state-owned enterprise­s, the liberaliza­tion of trade and investment and the advances of cutting-edge technologi­es that require higher skills. is trend has caused the income gap among workers to widen with increased “capital income” seen as a major reason for the immobiliza­tion of income inequality.

Such a state of income inequality, if le unattended, can lead to pent-up social discontent. is is exactly why the Chinese leadership recently had to declare the launch of a “Common Prosperity” policy to redress income inequality by redistribu­ting “donations” from electronic commerce and informatio­n technology giants such as Alibaba and Tencent. It is quite understand­able that the policy goal of Common Prosperity re ects the strong will of Chinese President Xi Jinping to hold on to power — he is known to be seeking a third term as Chinese Communist Party general secretary at the next party congress scheduled for this autumn.

U.S. NO DIFFERENT

Regarding income inequality, the United States is no di erent from China.

U.S. statistics clearly show that the U.S. middle class, as de ned on the basis of income strata, has been shrinking since 1970. For their part, wealthy Americans advocate a “small government,” demanding that public spending on social security and education be slashed. On the other hand, an overwhelmi­ng majority of low-income white workers tend to vote for conservati­ve politician­s who give little thought to their interests. ey do so because they are instilled with a prejudice that their hard-earned tax money is injected into the non-white population. ey think that neither labor unions nor the Democratic Party would help them. In the United States, there are many low-income people who think that their country is leaning toward oligarchy — namely the rule of a small handful of rich magnates. ey also think that the United States is paving the way toward statecra that is inconsiste­nt with a democracy that upholds equitable distributi­on of interests to a majority of its population.

Increased inequality and political corruption that are the defects — consequenc­es — of the intense energy generated by capitalism can be found both in China and the United States. However, to what extent such awed phenomena surface and in what forms they become palpable vary from country to country. Given that the U.S.-style capitalist system provides room for “self-puri cation” to work, thanks to freedom of speech and the press, cases of corruption are more likely to be uncovered. In this context, speech and the press can play a great role vis-a-vis political corruption.

Political corruption distorts the normality of market mechanisms, eventually weakening market forces. Bribery, in particular, threatens to restrain investment and, therefore, retard economic growth as funds are pocketed by those in power to enrich themselves, instead of being used for genuine investment.

Economists tell us that how harmful bribery is to economies depends on the extent to which autocratic leaders “monopolize” the act of corruption. When an autocratic leader and his or her family fully monopolize bribes, a national economy and its taxpayers su er less. Indonesia is o en referred to as a typical case of this as it achieved economic growth while then President Suharto was in power. Bribery committed by the Suharto family did not constitute a major growth constraint. In fact, the goal of the Suharto-era bureaucrat­ic discipline and control was not to eliminate bribes, but to enable his family to monopolize them. During his rule, Suharto and his family reportedly amassed a fortune of at least $15 billion, but Suharto-era bureaucrat­s kept the Indonesian markets functionin­g su ciently.

An opposite example of corruption can be found in the Russian Federation that emerged a er the collapse of the Soviet Union. In Russia, public of

cials with every job title assigned to every part of the government scrambled to receive bribes. As corruption was so widespread, the function of markets in Russia was signi cantly jeopardize­d. Compared with Indonesia, wealth accumulati­on through bribery in Russia might have occurred to a lesser extent. Neverthele­ss, with bribery rampant vertically and horizontal­ly in Russian society, an investment boom did not emerge, keeping the country as a state “sleeping on energy resources” and failing to grab opportunit­ies for robust economic growth.

Following the fall of the Soviet Union, many super-rich business tycoons called oligarchs exerted their political in uence on the privatizat­ion of stateowned energy enterprise­s. As such, there was no reason for these oligarchs to be at odds with Russian President Vladimir Putin.

The progress and immobiliza­tion of income inequality have the potential for triggering social instabilit­y.

WEALTHY TECH ELITE

As the above-cited examples show, the relationsh­ip between the wealthy and politician­s in power re ects the circumstan­ces of each country. When Xi came to power, China embarked on an “anti-corruption struggle,” apparently against the background that corruption had been terribly pervasive among authoritie­s at every level in every sector at both central and provincial administra­tion organizati­ons.

In China, its new elite, comprising those entreprene­urs who have amassed fortunes owing to rapid growth of the tech-related private sector, constitute a “new class” who have won out among the competitio­n. What kind of political power will this emerging class obtain from now on? As discussed in the early part of this article, the progress and immobiliza­tion of income inequality have the potential for triggering social instabilit­y. at said, what is equally important is the question of what kind of equilibriu­m the wealthy elite in the new class and the leadership of the Chinese Communist Party will come to a er confrontin­g each other — going through struggles and eventually agreeing on collusion. e degree of intrinsic instabilit­y in China’s domestic politics is greater than imagined. (July 22)

Inoki is a professor emeritus at Osaka University, where he also served as dean of the economics department. His previous posts included special professor at Aoyama Gakuin University and director general of the Internatio­nal Research Center for Japanese Studies.

 ?? Yomiuri Shimbun file photo ?? The headquarte­rs of Alibaba Group Holding Ltd. is seen in Hangzhou, China, in November 2020.
Yomiuri Shimbun file photo The headquarte­rs of Alibaba Group Holding Ltd. is seen in Hangzhou, China, in November 2020.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Japan