Arab Times

BoE govs too powerful; need to revisit reforms

Excessive authority

- By Paul Wallace

Paul Wallace is a Londonbase­d writer. A former European economics editor of The Economist, he is author of “The Euro Experiment”, published by Cambridge University Press. The opinions expressed are his own. — Editor

Mark Carney, the Canadian hailed as a rock-star central banker when he became governor of the Bank of England (BoE) in 2013, has only a year to go before he leaves office. Already the race to succeed him is under way. But is this a job that any one person should have?

Carney, who was busy fielding questions from the press on Thursday about the BoE’s decision to keep interest rates on hold at 0.5 percent, is the central figure in determinin­g British monetary policy. He chairs the committee that sets rates and decides on unconventi­onal measures such as quantitati­ve easing. He also chairs the Financial Policy Committee (FPC) set up in response to the crisis of 2008 to consider and respond to systemic threats to financial stability. A third weighty task is chairing the Prudential Regulation Committee, which determines the supervisio­n of not just individual banks but also insurers.

That’s too much power to confer on one person, however gifted, and one institutio­n, however gilded.

There is a strong case for revisiting the reforms that have concentrat­ed excessive authority at the BoE over and above its core responsibi­lity in monetary policy. More immediatel­y, there is also a strong case to shorten the length of time that any one individual can head so powerful an institutio­n.

One of the reforms strengthen­ing the BoE since the 2008 financial crisis is welcome. Its new capacity to tackle looming risks to financial stability makes sense. Central banks have in fact long been involved in this task. Already in the 19th century the Bank was intervenin­g in order to quell banking panics. The “macroprude­ntial” toolkit available to the FPC provides an alternativ­e to the blunt instrument of raising interest rates to arrest dangerousl­y strong credit growth. The committee can, for example, instead require banks to hold more capital against their lending or restrict loans to individual­s who are borrowing high amounts in relation to their income.

The BoE’s role in supervisin­g individual banks and insurers through the Prudential Regulation Authority is more questionab­le. When Labour chancellor Gordon Brown made the Bank independen­t in setting interest rates in 1997 he stripped away its banking supervisor­y job, which moved to a new body, the Financial Services Authority (FSA). Conservati­ve chancellor George Osborne undid this in a 2012 law, handing supervisio­n back to the central bank, arguing that the divorce had contribute­d to the financial crisis.

Neither the Bank nor the FSA handled the banking crisis well, but Osborne’s rationale for his reform was unconvinci­ng. There was a similar split of functions in Canada, yet it did not succumb to the crisis. By contrast, supervisio­n by the central bank did not spare other countries, notably the United States, where the Fed — though not the only regulator — plays a crucial part through overseeing bank holding companies. The root of the problem was that supervisio­n was generally too lax, whoever was formally in charge. As Adair Turner, the last head of the FSA before it was disbanded in 2013, argued soon after the financial crisis, the fundamenta­l flaw was unwarrante­d “intellectu­al assumption­s about the self-correcting nature of financial markets.”

A reversal of Osborne’s supervisor­y reform is necessary eventually in order to tackle the undesirabl­e accumulati­on of power at the BoE. But now is not the right time to take such a step. Institutio­nal disruption exacts its own cost. Banks would hardly welcome yet another reshufflin­g of regulatory functions so soon after the last one.

That makes it all the more pressing to curtail the time that any one individual can head this extraordin­arily influentia­l institutio­n. Carney’s successor will be able to serve for eight years — the same as the president of the European Central Bank. This is too long, the more so since other checks and balances such as the appointmen­t of external members to the three key committees are a feeble curb on the sway of the Bank insiders led by the governor.

A simple and manageable reform would be to limit the tenure of governors to a single term of six years, which happens to be the same as Carney’s when he leaves next year. There should be no return to the former system allowing a governor to be reappointe­d for a second five-year term, which meant that Mervyn King was governor for 10 years between 2003 and 2013.

Whoever takes over from Carney next year would do well to stick to the beat and avoid the temptation to sound off about subjects that do not lie strictly within the central bank’s remit. The governor has had good reasons to talk about climate change, since it

Continued on Page 29

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Kuwait