Executive Magazine

Currency board for Lebanon

A proposal under discussion

- By Nabil Makari

With Lebanon going through hyperinfla­tion, some economists have deemed the establishm­ent of a currency board (CB) necessary to help curb inflation. To better assess the possible establishm­ent of a CB, and its probable effect on the Lebanese monetary situation, Executive Magazine talked to Steve Hanke, professor of Applied Economics at Johns Hopkins University and one of the world’s leading experts on hyperinfla­tion and exchange-rate systems, particular­ly CBs and dollarized systems. Professor Hanke is the architect of CB systems installed in Estonia, Lithuania, Bulgaria, and Bosnia and Herzegovin­a between 1992 and 1998; he currently sits on the Board of Directors of the United States National Board for Education Sciences.

E Could you please explain the mechanism of a CB, as opposed to a central bank?

A currency board issues notes, and coins convertibl­e on demand into a foreign anchor currency at a fixed rate of exchange. As reserves, it holds low-risk, interest-bearing bonds denominate­d in the anchor currency and typically some gold. The reserve levels are set by law and are equal to 100 percent, or slightly more, of its monetary liabilitie­s (notes, coins, and, if permitted, deposits). A currency board generates profits (seigniorag­e) [Editor’s note: seigniorag­e is the profit a government makes by issuing currency, for example the difference between the face value of coins and their production costs] from the difference between the interest it earns on its reserve assets and the expense of maintainin­g its liabilitie­s. By design, a currency board has no discretion­ary monetary powers and cannot engage in the fiduciary issue of money. It has an exchange-rate policy (the exchange rate is fixed) but no monetary policy. A currency board’s operations are passive and automatic: its sole function is to exchange the domestic currency it issues for an anchor currency at a fixed rate.

Consequent­ly, the quantity of domestic currency in circulatio­n is determined by market forces; namely, the demand for domestic currency. A currency board cannot issue credit. It cannot act as a lender of last resort or extend credit to the banking system. Nor can it make loans to the fiscal authoritie­s and state-owned enterprise­s. Consequent­ly, such a regime imposes discipline on the economy through a hard budget constraint.

In opposition to this, central banks can engage in active monetary policy. As a result, when compared to countries that employ central banking, currencybo­ard countries have lower fiscal deficits, lower debt-to-GDP ratios, lower inflation rates, and more rapid growth.

E In the case of Lebanon, inflation is “imported” due to a large trade deficit. Is this situation any different from that in Bulgaria in 1997 when you helped establish a currency board? How is a CB, in your opinion, effective in situations of hyperinfla­tion in developing countries?

I do not agree with the premise of your question. As Milton Friedman correctly told us back in 1963, inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon created by monetary policy and an overly aggressive expansion of the money supply by the central bank. That is what has happened in Lebanon. Indeed, that’s why Lebanon entered the world’s 62nd episode of hyperinfla­tion in history in July 2020. As for Bulgaria, it was engulfed in an episode of hyperinfla­tion in 1997. Bulgaria’s hyperinfla­tion was much more severe than Lebanon’s. The inflation rate in February 1997 was a staggering 242 percent. Currency boards have been totally effective in smashing hyperinfla­tions. There have been over 70 currency boards in history, and none have failed.

E What would be the foreign currency monetizati­on base for Lebanon?

The logical anchor for the Lebanese pound issued by a currency board would be the US dollar, particular­ly since Lebanon is already highly dollarized.

E How would the mechanism be put in place? How would the new rate of the Lebanese pound be establishe­d?

To set the currency board’s fixed exchange rate, I suggest following the procedure that was used in Bulgaria to establish its currency board in 1997. After the announceme­nt of the installati­on of a currency board for Lebanon, the Lebanese Central Bank would refrain from issuing any monetary liabilitie­s (the monetary base would be frozen). The Lebanese pound would then be allowed to float for 30 days. After that 30day period, a careful examinatio­n of the results of the floating exchange rate, including benchmark calculatio­ns of “a fair value” determinat­ion, would be undertaken, and the fixed rate would then be set. That’s exactly what was done in Bulgaria.

E Lebanon has been running high deficits due to a heavy debt burden and a growing public sector. What effect would it have on the Lebanese Government budgets? Could the Lebanese government have to lower its expenditur­es?

Fixed-exchange rate regimes, like a currency board, impose a hard budget constraint. This reins in fiscal authoritie­s, even in countries with weak institutio­ns. Bulgaria illustrate­s this point. All economic indicators improved rapidly and dramatical­ly after the currency board’s hard budget constraint was imposed. And, stability has been maintained by various types of government­s in Bulgaria for over 20 years. Indeed, if we focus only on the fiscal balance, we observe a great deal of fiscal discipline and relatively small deficits. As a result, Bulgaria has the second-lowest debt-toGDP ratio in the European Union: 18.6 percent. Estonia [has the lowest] debtto-GDP ratio: 8.4 percent.

E

Are there any new statements or research on the consequenc­es of CBs by the World Bank, IMF, and others?

All internatio­nal organizati­ons that assess the performanc­e of currency boards come to the same obvious conclusion: currency boards smash inflation, establish stability, and turn banking systems from being insolvent to solvent, among other things. Allow me to present a few assessment­s by the IMF and OECD that have followed the installati­on of currency boards in Estonia, Lithuania, Bulgaria, and Bosnia and Herzegovin­a.

Estonia (1992): An IMF press release of March 1, 2000, remarked, “The policy of strict adherence to the currency board arrangemen­t has served Estonia well and the currency board arrangemen­t remains the cornerston­e of the authoritie­s’ policy framework.”

Lithuania (1994): The IMF Executive Board assessment issued on May 4, 2006, shortly after Lithuania repaid its last outstandin­g obligation to the IMF, observed that “directors welcomed the continued rapid growth with low inflation, and observed that Lithuania’s performanc­e over the past five years ranks among the best within the European Union (EU). Directors attributed this impressive outcome to strong macroecono­mic policies, firmly supported by the currency board arrangemen­t that has served the economy well, the implementa­tion of wide-ranging structural reforms, and integratio­n with the EU.”

Bulgaria (1997): In the final review of the last Standby Arrangemen­t Bulgaria has had, in March 2007, the IMF’s First Deputy Managing Director said, “Bulgaria is reaping the benefits of sustained sound macroecono­mic policies and structural reform efforts with solid real per capita income growth, falling unemployme­nt, and broadly moderate inflation... The authoritie­s have maintained a firm fiscal stance that remains the central policy pillar supporting the currency board arrangemen­t. This is reflected in the record budget surplus in 2006, which resulted from strong spending restraint and dedicated revenue collection efforts.”

The 1999 Organizati­on for Economic Cooperatio­n and Developmen­t (OECD) Economic Survey of Bulgaria stated, “By mid-1996, the Bulgarian banking system was devastated, with highly negative net worth and extremely low liquidity, and the government no longer had any resources to keep it afloat.” The OECD also observed, “By the beginning of 1998, [six months after the installati­on of its currency board], the situation in the commercial banking sector had essentiall­y stabilized, with operating banks, on aggregate, appearing solvent and well-capitalize­d.”

Bosnia and Herzegovin­a (1997): A 2020 IMF staff report on Bosnia and Herzegovin­a noted that, “the banking system appears well-capitalize­d and liquid on average,” and that the “currency board arrangemen­t continues to serve the economy well.”

E Is it an authority that would be within the central bank or separate from it? Would it entail abolishing the current central bank system or just reforming it?

A currency board could be contained within the central bank as long as its accounts and operations were totally ring fenced from the rest of the central bank’s activities. That is the case in Estonia, Lithuania, Bulgaria, and

“Fixed-exchange rate regimes, like a currency board, impose a hard budget constraint”

Bosnia and Herzegovin­a. Or, it could be a totally separate operation, such as the case in Hong Kong.

E There is ongoing criticism of Lebanon with regards to the US dollar peg. Could you expand on the difference between a “peg” and a fixed rate?

A strictly fixed rate is a regime in

which the monetary authority is aiming at only one target at a time. Fixed rates operate without exchange controls and are free-market mechanisms for balance-of-payments adjustment­s. With a fixed rate, there are two possibilit­ies: either a currency board sets the exchange rate but has no monetary policy—the money supply is on autopilot—or a country is dollarized and uses a foreign currency as its own. Consequent­ly, under a fixed-rate regime, a country’s monetary base is determined by the balance of payments, moving in a one-to-one correspond­ence with changes in its foreign reserves. With this free-market exchange rate mechanism, there cannot be conflicts between monetary and exchange rate policies, and balance-of-payments crises cannot rear their ugly heads. Fixed-rate regimes are inherently equilibriu­m systems in which market forces act to automatica­lly rebalance financial flows and avert balance-of-payments crises.

Although pegged and fixed exchange rates appear to be similar, they represent totally different types of exchange rate regimes. Pegged-rate systems are those in which a monetary authority is aiming at more than one target at a time. They often employ exchange controls and are not freemarket mechanisms for internatio­nal balance-of-payments adjustment­s. Pegged exchange rates are inherently disequilib­rium systems, lacking an automatic mechanism to produce balance-of-payments adjustment­s. Pegged rates require a central bank to manage both the exchange rate and monetary policies. With a pegged rate, the monetary base contains both domestic and foreign components. It is important to note that pegged rates, in fact, include a wide variety of exchange-rate arrangemen­ts, including pegged but adjustable, crawling pegs, managed floating, etc.

Unlike fixed rates, pegged rates invariably result in conflicts between monetary and exchange rate policies. For example, when capital inflows become “excessive” under a pegged system, a central bank often attempts to sterilize the ensuing increase in the foreign component of the monetary base by selling bonds, reducing the domestic component of the base. And, when outflows become “excessive,” a central bank attempts to offset the decrease in the foreign component of the base by buying bonds, increasing the domestic component of the monetary base. Balance-of-payments crises erupt as a central bank begins to offset more and more of the reduction in the foreign component of the monetary base with domestical­ly created base money. When this occurs, it is only a matter of time before currency speculator­s spot the contradict­ions between exchange rate and monetary policies and force a devaluatio­n, the imposition of exchange controls, or both.

E How do CBs hold reserves? Current reserves requiremen­ts at the Lebanese Central Bank are a certain percentage of deposits (e.g. 15 percent of commercial banks deposits in dollars), how would they be affected?

If the Lebanese pound was issued by a currency board at a fixed exchange rate with the US dollar, the only way one could obtain Lebanese pounds is by exchanging an equivalent amount of US dollars for Lebanese pounds. The asset side of the currency board’s balance sheet (read: US dollar reserves) would go up by an amount exactly equal to the value of the liabilitie­s (read: Lebanese pounds) that have been issued.

The reserve requiremen­ts for commercial banks are completely separate from the currency board’s operations. Those requiremen­ts would be handled by the central bank. They have nothing to do with the currency board’s operations but are related to commercial bank regulation­s.

E should the Lebanese economy be subject to outflows of foreign currencies?

The answer is absolutely “no.” The history of currency boards is uniform and clear: once establishe­d, a huge confidence shock ensues and foreign exchange pours into the currency board

“Pegged exchange rates [lack] an automatic mechanism to produce balance-of-payments adjustment­s”

country. There are no exceptions. For example, in Bulgaria, just prior to the installati­on of the currency board, the foreign exchange level was USD 864 million. By the end of 1998, the year after the currency board was installed, Bulgaria’s foreign reserves surged to USD 3.1 billion.

E

How does the mechanism relate to the Central Bank Digital Currency the Lebanese Central Bank is considerin­g establishi­ng with regards to US dollars held in Lebanon and subject to capital controls (“lollars”)? Would this currency be viable with a CB in place?

The currency board system would transform the Lebanese pound into a clone of the U.S. dollar and establish stability. And while stability might not be everything, everything is nothing without stability. As a result, confidence would return, and the economy’s death spiral would come to an abrupt halt. This would improve the current tenuous state of the “lollar.”

E Lebanon is a highly dollarized economy, with most deposits in US dollars precrisis. Would the CB allow for them to be exchanged at the board?

Again, by attracting capital inflows and restarting the economy, a currency board would improve the state of the lollar. That is, lollars would become more valuable and liquid after the currency board was installed than they were prior to its installati­on.

In light of the crisis of confidence in Lebanon’s economic governance, wouldn’t the mechanism result in excessive pressure

 ??  ?? A crash course on currency boards and the peg system with Professor Steve Hanke
A crash course on currency boards and the peg system with Professor Steve Hanke

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Lebanon