The New Zealand Herald

Time to try some Danish?

More secure incomes could encourage people to switch jobs and embrace change

- Brian Fallow brian.fallow@nzherald.co.nz

Removing the link between income security and job security, and focusing more on the income side, would make the economy better equipped to seize the opportunit­ies technologi­cal innovation provides, the Productivi­ty Commission argues.

The economy has been pretty good at generating jobs, the commission notes in the second draft report from its inquiry into technologi­cal change, disruption and the future of work. Productivi­ty and income growth, on the other hand, not so much. Not by a long chalk.

Within the OECD club of developed economies, New Zealand ranks high for prime-age employment, for example. That is the proportion of people aged between 15 and 64 who are employed.

But, at the same time, we are laggards in output per hour worked, which is fundamenta­l to incomes. Labour productivi­ty remains around 40 per cent less than the average of the top half of OECD countries.

New Zealand (with Australia and Mexico) is an outlier in not having mandatory unemployme­nt insurance, to soften the income loss associated with job loss. The gap between a wage or salary, and the dole (designed only to prevent extreme hardship) is particular­ly brutal.

It is a system more likely to produce inertia than dynamism in the labour market — a greater reluctance to change jobs or to embrace technologi­cal change which might imperil a job, than would otherwise be the case. Tax-based data indicate the rate of the job-to-job flow — people leaving one job to immediatel­y start another — is subdued by historical standards.

It can also mean that people who become unemployed are more likely to take a new job for which they are over-qualified. That can result in a persistent fall in pay known in the jargon as “income scarring”, and they are less able to afford to retrain at their own expense.

“High income economies are characteri­sed by highly skilled workers with high-capital-intensity jobs and the rapid uptake of emerging technologi­es,” the commission says. The result is high labour productivi­ty and incomes.

“By contrast the New Zealand economy appears stuck with low wages, low productivi­ty growth and low technology adoption.”

More workers do grow the economy, at least in absolute terms. “However, this approach is a bit like recruiting more people to push a broken-down car rather than fixing its engine.”

So would some form of income smoothing, which made the loss of a job less financiall­y scary, boost productivi­ty?

Commission­er Andrew Sweet says there is pretty clear evidence on attitudes towards technology, that some countries are more open to it than others. “We don’t have robust evidence of that link, as opposed to correlatio­n, but my argument would be that firms and unions are going to be more resistant to anything that increases the chances of job loss without income smoothing.”

The commission is not saying that a precarious gig economy driven by automation is either evident now or in the offing, rather that an approach which shifts the focus from job security to income security would be a sensible precaution and make the economy more resilient.

It suggests three forms that could take. ● One would be an unemployme­nt insurance scheme. It could be government­run, as ACC is now, or a regulated commercial market, like the Danes’.

ACC is the most familiar form of social insurance, providing a degree of income protection during recovery from an injury. As it applies to the self-employed as well as employees, it avoids one of the pitfalls of some models, like the French, of creating a two-tier labour market with very high protection for some workers and very low protection for others.

Designing an unemployme­nt insurance regime would require detailed and careful analysis, Sweet said, but would have the benefit of a lot of internatio­nal experience of what works and what does not.

In any case, there is no free lunch. New Zealand is unusual in not having (ACC apart) payroll taxes to cover social security costs. As a result, the tax wedge on wages (the difference between what it costs to employ someone and their take-home pay) consists almost entirely of their income tax. It is one of the lowest such gaps in the OECD.

Funding unemployme­nt insurance would widen that wedge. The trick would be not to widen it so much as to create a deterrent to employing people in the first place.

● The second option the commission suggests is more akin to KiwiSaver — except that it would be compulsory. It is a system of portable individual redundancy accounts, built up while workers have a job, but which they can draw on if they lose it (or retire).

Such a scheme is likely to require some degree of government backstop for people early in their working lives or on low incomes.

● The third option would be to use the existing welfare system to provide increased but time-limited income support after job loss.

However, integratin­g that with the current system of household-based means testing would be a nightmare, and of course it would impose a cost on taxpayers.

“The welfare system is all designed around the avoidance of severe hardship and deprivatio­n, but what we are arguing is that for job loss an economic, dynamic efficiency lens is more appropriat­e,” Sweet said. “Why would you only provide assistance to a small subset of those made unemployed?”

If the focus is on job security, there is an inherent tension between that and productivi­ty-enhancing things like free trade, openness to foreign investment and flexible labour markets, he said.

By contrast the Danes — who are the poster boys of the “flexicurit­y” model, with its emphasis on income security, that the commission is advocating — have managed to have their cake and eat it, Sweet says.

“The OECD judges their labour market to be more flexible than ours and that their approach to foreign investment is more liberal than ours.” Their productivi­ty is around one-third higher than ours and incomes reflect that.

“Obviously there is a direct financial cost to funding these things,” Sweet said. “But I would argue there isn’t a broader economic cost. We are not saying ‘ Can we afford to slow down growth or reduce productivi­ty by doing this?’ There is a virtuous relationsh­ip.”

— Submission­s on the commission’s draft report are open until February 7 next year.

[Adding more workers] is a bit like recruiting more people to push a broken-down car rather than fixing its engine.

The Productivi­ty Commission

 ?? Photo / Bloomberg ?? Denmark offers more income security and job flexibilit­y than NZ — and has much higher productivi­ty.
Photo / Bloomberg Denmark offers more income security and job flexibilit­y than NZ — and has much higher productivi­ty.
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from New Zealand