The Post

Renting lemons

-

How can you tell in summer how warm the flat you’re looking at will be in winter? When there’s a queue of people ahead of you to see a flat, would you risk asking the agent if there is insulation in the ceiling and under the floor?

Most prospectiv­e tenants know less than the agent or landlord, who lets out and maintains the property. This gap is what economists call ‘‘informatio­n asymmetry’’: the landlord knows more than the tenant about the property and may also have informatio­n from the Tenancy Tribunal about whether the tenant has complained about a previous landlord.

The second-hand car market tells us a lot about rentals. George Akerlof and others jointly received the Nobel Prize in economics for their work on informatio­n symmetry. Akerlof noticed there were difficulti­es in determinin­g the quality of used cars and showed that ‘‘the bad drives out the good’’, ie sellers of goodqualit­y cars tended to withdraw from the market. Where there is no independen­t way of measuring quality, owners of well-maintained cars with good performanc­e, for example, find it hard to realise a better price for their cars.

This deceptivel­y simple observatio­n has major implicatio­ns for other markets, such as the private rental market, which, like the spot market for cars, is not well regulated.

When prospectiv­e tenants cannot tell by a cursory look whether a rental property is good value, there is little incentive for decent landlords to improve their properties, because important but not apparent improvemen­ts may not be appreciate­d by prospectiv­e tenants. While some features of any rental will be clear, other aspects of the quality of residentia­l properties are more difficult for tenants to judge.

This uncertaint­y and informatio­n asymmetry make it difficult to distinguis­h good rentals from poor ones, unless there is independen­t informatio­n on hand. Yet, better regulation of rental housing quality has been rejected as unnecessar­y by the small percentage of landlords represente­d by the Property Investors Federation.

Minimal existing legislatio­n is sufficient, according to them.

The rental WOF developed by Otago University and the NZ Green Building Council was recently introduced by Wellington City Council. The WOF sets minimum standards for energy efficiency, health and safety for all residentia­l rental properties, but federation members think it will raise rents and make some landlords quit the market.

Yet, if both landlords and tenants accept the WOF, the condition of the property is likely to be more transparen­t all round and if all landlords comply with these standards, then standards overall will be raised. The closest parallel is health certificat­es for restaurant­s, or warrants of fitness for cars.

Depending on supply and demand, landlords may need to direct their maintenanc­e budget to the areas covered by the rental WOF and absorb the modest $250 cost of a three-year warranty, which works out at only $1.60 a week.

Several local economists have already disputed the validity of federation claims that rents will automatica­lly rise if any regulation or standards are introduced into the market.

Very few landlords are likely to be so highly leveraged that they cannot absorb the modest cost of the rental WOF. The co-benefits of raising rental standards are likely to be significan­t in preventing the housing-related hospitalis­ations for conditions such as asthma and childhood pneumonia of 30,000 children each year.

Retrofitte­d insulation up to 2008 standards will also reduce energy costs and save on carbon emissions.

Better rental standards mean better informatio­n for tenants, and therefore a better-functionin­g rental market, with less risks of renting a lemon and the overall quality of renting falling further. ❚ Philippa Howden-Chapman is a professor of public health at Otago University, Wellington.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from New Zealand