The Press

Overcoming the cult of governance

The governance obsession has spread throughout government and community organisati­ons.

- Rob Campbell

Aotearoa seems to me to be overgovern­ed in many important respects. And worse than that, ineffectiv­ely governed. That might seem odd coming from someone who has been in a wide range of governance roles over a long period. But the more experience I have the more I doubt the universal efficacy of the role.

Whether it is a start-up, a community organisati­on, a government agency or whatever it may be, there is an immediate inclinatio­n, even compulsion, to appoint a board. It’s what we do here. Sometimes it might be appropriat­e but the immediate assumption that it is an essential aspect of running anything effectivel­y and efficientl­y is simply wrong.

Part of the problem is simply assuming that everything should be run like a business. The model of operating any activity which dominates our thinking is the commercial model. This prevails despite the overwhelmi­ng evidence that the commercial model, for all of its strengths, very often fails and more often is a vehicle for shifting costs and appropriat­ing benefits.

There is risk in all human activities. It is natural that we try to take advantage of upside potential or risk and limit the occurrence and impact of the down side. We have an illusion that appointing a board is effective risk management but there is not much evidence of this happening and more than a little where even “good governance” does not manage risk all that well.

The model of governance that we have derives from what have been called “agency” issues. In business the perception is that investors in the equity and debt supporting the business cannot simply trust the managers to do the right thing for those interests. Hence a board is there to monitor and direct the management in accord with those interests. Interestin­gly such boards are appointed by and accountabl­e to the equity investors in the first instance. In practice debt investors protect their interests contractua­lly and typically much more effectivel­y than equity.

Debt investors may just be tougher and smarter.

As board practice has evolved a much wider set of responsibi­lities for directors has been establishe­d by law and social expectatio­n. But it is a very moot point as to whether such wider interests are most effectivel­y represente­d in business practice by a board. In matters such as safety, cybersecur­ity, environmen­tal compliance and others a commercial board often lacks expertise and, given the range of such issues, is likely always to lack expertise. As enterprise­s get larger and more complex the likelihood that even the most diligent board has genuine depth of knowledge and power to direct decreases. So even in the commercial context we may doubt whether the old model has it right.

Directors and their organisati­ons try to deal with this. By training and good practice models an effort is made. But time and time again we see enterprise­s whose boards appear to meet these practices, and to have senior and experience­d compositio­n, fail to meet commercial objectives or compliance when unusual pressures arise. Some of this is to do with the fact that economics trumps governance, but some also comes from a model which is not well suited to the tasks. Typically enterprise­s spend excessive time in collecting informatio­n and reporting to boards to great cost, often limited effect and with clear distractio­n from hands-on management of the real issues. Rather than agents of accountabi­lity, boards often drift into becoming agents of protection and obfuscatio­n. Protecting their own interests and those of the management they are close to. And that is just in the commercial world.

The governance obsession has spread throughout government and community organisati­ons. Some of it is frankly ludicrous.

Most such boards are simply excuses for more meetings, more reports, with no real clarity on purpose or accountabi­lity. At best their powers are often simply advisory. They become mechanisms for delay and prevaricat­ion amongst management who spend time gaming them as much as being accountabl­e to them.

This is not always wrong in itself – elected representa­tives probably should hold direct accountabi­lity and authority without these intermedia­ry boards. You can add your own names, but we can all think of boards at various government levels that could be removed without pain and significan­t gain.

When I look objectivel­y at business or community organisati­ons now I find very seldom indeed that the addition of a board is really in the best interests of the activity. Usually more decisive and accountabl­e management is the key, along with flexible and genuinely expert advice as required. Leaders, not governors.

Recently I had the opportunit­y to meet with young people from a range of sectors. As is all too common, they were interested in how they might progress in a “governance career”. I hope I managed to put them off. I always try.

People with real skills, energy and passion are better applying those directly than pretending to “govern” others.

Rob Campbell CNZM has an extensive background in trade unionism, business leadership, governance and public service. He is chancellor of AUT, and the chair of Ara Ake and NZ Rural Land.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from New Zealand