Business a.m.

Could Ultra-Low Interest Rates Be Contractio­nary?

- ERNEST LIU ATIF MIAN AMIR SUFI Ernest Liu is a professor at the Bendheim Center for Finance at Princeton University. Atif Mian is a professor at Princeton University and Director of the Julis-Rabinowitz Center for Public Policy and Finance at the Woodrow

CHICAGO – The real (inflationa­djusted) yield on ten-year US treasuries is currently zero, and has been extremely low for most of the past eight years. Outside of the United States, meanwhile, 40% of investment-grade bonds have negative nominal yields. And most recently, the European Central Bank further reduced its deposit rate to -0.5% as part of a new package of economic stimulus measures for the eurozone.

Low interest rates have traditiona­lly been viewed as positive for economic growth. But our recent research suggests that this may not be the case. Instead, extremely low interest rates may lead to slower growth by increasing market concentrat­ion. If this argument is correct, it implies that reducing interest rates further will not save the global economy from stagnation.

The traditiona­l view holds that when long-term rates fall, the net present value of future cash flows increases, making it more attractive for firms to invest in productivi­ty-enhancing technologi­es. Low interest rates therefore have an expansiona­ry effect on the economy through stronger productivi­ty growth.

But if low interest rates also have an opposite strategic effect, they reduce the incentive for firms to invest in boosting productivi­ty. Moreover, as long-term real rates approach zero, this strategic contractio­nary effect dominates. So, in today’s low-interest-rate environmen­t, a further decline in rates will most probably slow the economy by reducing productivi­ty growth.

This strategic effect works through industry competitio­n. Although lower interest rates encourage all firms in a sector to invest more, the incentive to do so is greater for market leaders than for followers. As a result, industries become more monopolist­ic over time as long-term rates fall.

Our research indicates that an industry leader and follower interact strategica­lly in the sense that each carefully considers the other’s investment policy when deciding on its own. In particular, because industry leaders respond more strongly to a decline in the interest rate, followers become discourage­d and stop investing as leaders get too far ahead. And because leaders then face no serious competitiv­e threat, they too ultimately stop investing and become “lazy monopolist­s.”

Perhaps the best analogy is with two runners engaged in a perpetual race around a track. The runner who finishes each lap in the lead earns a prize. And it is the present discounted value of these potential prizes that encourages the runners to improve their position.

Now, suppose that sometime during the race, the interest rate used to discount future prizes falls. Both runners would then want to run faster because future prizes are worth more today. This is the traditiona­l economic effect. But the incentive to run faster is greater for the runner in the lead, because she is closer to the prizes and hence more likely to get them.

The lead runner therefore increases her pace by more than the follower, who becomes discourage­d because she is now less likely to catch up. If the discourage­ment effect is large enough, then the follower simply gives up. Once that happens, the leader also slows down, as she no longer faces a competitiv­e threat. And our research suggests that this strategic discourage­ment effect will dominate as the interest rate used to discount the value of the prizes approaches zero.

In a real-world economy, the strategic effect is likely to be even stronger, because industry leaders and followers do not face the same interest rate in practice. Followers typically pay a spread over the interest rate paid by market leaders – and this spread tends to persist as interest rates fall. A cost-of-funding advantage like this for industry leaders would further strengthen the strategic contractio­nary impact of low interest rates.

This contractio­nary effect helps to explain a number of important global economic patterns. First, the decline in interest rates that began in the early 1980s has been associated with growing market concentrat­ion, rising corporate profits, weaker business dynamism, and declining productivi­ty growth. All are consistent with our model. Moreover, the timing of the aggregate trends also matches the model: the data show an increase in market concentrat­ion and profitabil­ity from the 1980s through 2000, followed by a slowdown in productivi­ty growth starting in 2005.

Second, the model makes some unique empirical prediction­s that we test against the data. For example, a stock portfolio that is long on industry leaders and short on industry followers generates positive returns when interest rates fall. More important, this effect becomes even stronger when the rate is low to begin with. This, too, is consistent with what the model predicts.

The contractio­nary effect of ultra-low interest rates has important implicatio­ns for the global economy. Our analysis suggests that with interest rates already extremely low, a further decline will have a negative economic impact via increased market concentrat­ion and lower productivi­ty growth. So, far from saving the global economy, lower interest rates may cause it more pain.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Nigeria