Business a.m.

Negotiator­s Should Decrease Concession­s Across Rounds

- Kian Siong Tey

SIGNALLING YOUR BOTTOM line reduces your counterpar­ty’s ambitions. Zero-sum negotiatio­ns, such as bargaining over the price of a product, are ubiquitous. Salary discussion­s are, of course, an example of consequenc­e as well. In all cases, one of the biggest issues on both sides is figuring out just how much room there is for negotiatio­n. And since no one can read minds, every small cue counts.

Among the cues negotiator­s seize upon are concession­s, or how an initial offer changes over time. Concession­s can signal that negotiator­s want to settle quickly, that they lack ambition, or maybe that they want to encourage reciprocit­y. We sought to shed light on how negotiator­s view – and react to – changes in the magnitude of concession­s over time.

This is important because there are different ways of making concession­s. We asked 150 experience­d profession­als to put themselves in a seller’s shoes and tell us the sequence of offers they would make to a buyer over four rounds of negotiatio­n. The most common strategy, used by 40 percent of participan­ts, consisted in reducing their price by the exact same amount across rounds.

Only 6 percent of participan­ts thought it best to decrease the size of their concession­s over rounds. To illustrate, this could mean the following: If they intend to reduce their price by US$200, they might first reduce it by $100, then $60, $30 and $10 successive­ly, as opposed to consistent­ly reducing it by $50 four times.

When we asked participan­ts why they wouldn’t taper their concession­s, the biggest reason (mentioned by 31 percent of respondent­s) was that, in their opinion, this strategy was ineffectiv­e, or at least less effective than other patterns of concession­s. The second most noted reason (23 percent) was that they had simply not thought about that option.

Yet, as we show in our recent paper, when concession­s are made over a series of rounds, tapering down the size of each concession is your best bet in a zero-sum negotiatio­n. The ever-shrinking size of each successive concession signals that you are reaching your bottom line (whether this is real or not). Counterpar­ts are attuned to such cues and when they recognise the pattern, it compels them to lower their ambitions in order to prevent an impasse.

Negotiatin­g the rent for an apartment

In one study, we told participan­ts – MBA students of diverse nationalit­ies – that they were looking to rent a one-bedroom flat in the city centre and that the monthly rent for such flats in nearby suburban areas was between $700-$1,000. We asked them to negotiate with a simulated landlord (a bot named “Casey”) the rent of a suitable apartment that was advertised at $1,500.

Casey was programmed to make either constant or decreasing concession­s over three rounds of negotiatio­n. Thus, some participan­ts received counteroff­ers that were $100 cheaper every time ($1,400, $1,300, $1,200). Others received counteroff­ers in a tapering pattern that suggested Casey’s bottom line was near ($1,300, $1,225 and $1,200). The negotiatio­n ended automatica­lly if the participan­t made an offer higher than the next programmed counteroff­er.

What was of interest to us was the fourth and final offer the remaining participan­ts would make in response to Casey’s $1,200 counteroff­er (the same in both scenarios). Those who obtained repeated $100 concession­s offered $811 on average for the flat, while those who had seen Casey’s concession­s taper off didn’t dare to go too low and offered $879 on average.

Make the decrease salient

In another study, we asked executive MBA students, also of diverse nationalit­ies, to negotiate over email the signing bonus of an otherwise agreed-upon job offer. Participan­ts either took the role of the recruiter or the candidate. They were told that the average bonus in the field was $23,000. The first offer of all recruiters was $20,000. Some recruiters were told to increase that offer by $2,000, then $750, then $250 over subsequent rounds. The rest were instructed to make a one-time concession, immediatel­y increasing the offer to $23,000.

Here again, of interest to us was the final counteroff­er candidates made once in possession of the $23,000 offer. Candidates who had received tapering concession­s suggestive of a near bottom line proposed to settle at $23,650 on average, while candidates who had received no such cues were a lot more ambitious with a final counteroff­er of $28,161.

In yet another study, we found that the tapering effect worked best when applied at a moderate pace. Participan­ts negotiated the purchase of a $1,500 second-hand laptop with seller “Alex” (also a bot). A group received three concession­s of the same amount from Alex. Others received three concession­s, but at various paces.

Alex received the highest average counteroff­er ($975) after decreasing concession­s at a moderate pace, as opposed to tapering concession­s slowly ($957) or going with a huge first concession followed by mini-ones ($937). Keeping concession­s constant led to the worst outcome for Alex, as the buyers’ final offer only amounted to $909 on average.

The tapering of the concession­s needs to be salient enough for the counterpar­ty to notice it, but not so steep so as to make your original price seem like a fluke followed by manipulati­ve tiny concession­s.

The cues you send influence your counterpar­t

Decreasing concession­s over several rounds of negotiatio­n is a strategy taught in business schools, but our paper is the first to back it up with data. When applied to zero-sum negotiatio­ns, this strategy allows you to secure a bigger slice of the pie as it signals your bottom line and makes your counterpar­ty worry about a possible impasse. In a supplement­ary study, we showed that clearly labelling your final offer as your “bottom line” strengthen­ed the effect.

While your counterpar­ty may have started out with a certain sense of what your bottom line might be, they can’t know for sure. As a result, the cues you send can influence them. The downside of this strategy is that it does require some planning. Most negotiator­s expect to make concession­s, but they don’t like to plan them. Yet, they would do well to chart the path from their first to their last offer.

If you find that your counterpar­t is using this strategy on you, your best defence is to never lose sight of the target you set for yourself at the start of the negotiatio­n. In our research, this counterstr­ategy was effective at keeping a negotiator’s ambitions intact.

This is an adaptation of an article published in Harvard Business Review.

Kian Siong Tey is a PhD candidate at INSEAD.

Michael Schaerer is an Assistant Professor of Organisati­onal Behaviour & Human Resources at Singapore Management University’s Lee Kong Chian School of Business. He was awarded a PhD from INSEAD.

Nikhil Madan is an Assistant Professor of Organisati­onal Behaviour at Indian School of Business.

Roderick Swaab is a Professor of Organisati­onal Behaviour and the INSEAD Dutch Alumni Fellow in Leadership, Diversity and Governance at INSEAD. He is also the Academic Director of the PhD Programme at INSEAD.

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Nigeria