Business a.m.

Is the New Stagflatio­n Policy-Proof?

- NOURIEL ROUBINI BRUNELLO ROSA Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2022. www.project-syndicate.org

NEW YORK – The global economy has suffered two large negative supply-side shocks, first from the COVID-19 pandemic and now from Russian President Vladimir Putin’s invasion of Ukraine. The war has further disrupted economic activity and resulted in higher inflation, because its short-term effects on supply and commodity prices have combined with the consequenc­es of excessive monetary and fiscal stimulus across advanced economies, especially the United States but also in other advanced economies.

Putting aside the war’s profound long-term geopolitic­al ramificati­ons, the immediate economic impact has come in the form of higher energy, food, and industrial metal prices. This, together with additional disruption­s to global supply chains, has exacerbate­d the stagflatio­nary conditions that emerged during the pandemic.

A stagflatio­nary negative supply shock poses a dilemma for central bankers. Because they care about anchoring inflation expectatio­ns, they need to normalize monetary policy quickly, even though that will lead to a further slowdown and possibly a recession. But because they also care about growth, they need to proceed slowly with policy normalizat­ion, even though that risks deanchorin­g inflation expectatio­ns and triggering a wageprice spiral.

Fiscal policymake­rs also face a difficult choice. In the presence of a persistent negative supply shock, increasing transfers or reducing taxes is not optimal, because it prevents private demand from falling in response to the reduction in supply.

Fortunatel­y, the European government­s that are now pursuing higher spending on defense and decarboniz­ation can count these forms of stimulus as investment­s – rather than as current spending – that would reduce supply bottleneck­s over time. Still, any additional spending will increase debt and come on top of the excessive response to the pandemic, which accompanie­d a massive fiscal expansion with monetary accommodat­ion and de facto monetizati­on of the debts incurred.

To be sure, as the pandemic has receded (at least in advanced economies), government­s have embarked on a very gradual fiscal consolidat­ion, and central banks have begun policy-normalizat­ion programs to rein in price inflation and prevent a de-anchoring of inflation expectatio­ns. But the war in Ukraine has introduced a new complicati­on as stagflatio­nary pressures are now higher.

Fiscal-monetary coordinati­on was the hallmark of

Nouriel Roubini, Professor Emeritus of Economics at New York University’s Stern School of Business, is Chief Economist at Atlas Capital Team. Brunello Rosa, CEO of Rosa & Roubini Associates, is a visiting professor at Bocconi University.

the pandemic response. But now, whereas central banks have stuck with their newly hawkish stance, fiscal authoritie­s have enacted easing policies (such as tax credits and reduction in fuel taxes) to soften the blow from surging energy prices. Thus, coordinati­on seems to have given way to a division of labor, with central banks addressing inflation and legislatur­es tackling growth and supply issues.

In principle, most government­s have three economic objectives: supporting economic activity, ensuring price stability, and keeping longterm interest rates or sovereign spreads in check through persistent monetizati­on of public debt. An additional goal is geopolitic­al: Putin’s invasion must be met with a response that both punishes Russia and deters others from considerin­g similar acts of aggression.

The instrument­s for pursuing these objectives are monetary policy, fiscal policy, and regulatory frameworks. Each is being used, respective­ly, to address inflation, support economic activity, and enforce sanctions. Moreover, until recently, re-investment policies and flight-to-safety capital flows had kept longterm interest rates low by maintainin­g downward pressure on ten-year Treasury and German bond yields.

Owing to this confluence of factors, the system has reached a temporary equilibriu­m, with each of the three objectives being partly addressed. But recent market signals – the significan­t rise in long-term rates and intraeuro spreads – suggest that this policy mix will become inadequate, producing new disequilib­ria.

Additional fiscal stimulus and sanctions on Russia may feed inflation, thus partly defeating monetary policymake­rs’ efforts. Moreover, central banks’ drive to tame inflation via higher policy rates will become inconsiste­nt with accommodat­ive balance-sheet policies, and this could result in higher longer-term interest rates and sovereign spreads, which are already drifting sharply upwards.

Central banks will have to continue juggling the incompatib­le objectives of taming inflation while also keeping long-term rates (or intra-eurozone spreads) low through balance-sheet maintenanc­e policies. And all the while, government­s will continue to fuel inflationa­ry pressures with fiscal stimulus and persistent sanctions.

Over time, tighter monetary policies may cause a growth slowdown or outright recession. But another risk is that monetary policy will be constraine­d by the threat of a debt trap. With private and public debt levels at historic highs as a share of GDP, central bankers can take policy normalizat­ion only so far before risking a financial crash in debt and equity markets.

At that point, government­s, under pressure from disgruntle­d citizens, may be tempted to come to the rescue with price and wage caps and administra­tive controls to tame inflation. These measures have proved unsuccessf­ul in the past (causing, for example, rationing) – not least in the stagflatio­nary 1970s – and there is no reason to think that this time would be different. If anything, some government­s would make matters even worse by, say, re-introducin­g automatic indexation mechanisms for salaries and pensions.

In such a scenario, all policymake­rs would realize the limitation­s of their own tools. Central banks would see that their ability to control inflation is circumscri­bed by the need to continue monetizing public and private debts. And government­s would see that their ability to maintain sanctions on Russia is constraine­d by the negative impacts on their own economies (in terms of both overall activity and inflation).

There are two possible endgames. Policymake­rs may abandon one of their objectives, leading to higher inflation, lower growth, higher long-term interest rates, or softer sanctions – accompanie­d perhaps by lower equity indices. Alternativ­ely, policymake­rs may settle for only partly achieving each goal, leading to a suboptimal macro outcome of higher inflation, lower growth, higher long-term rates, and softer sanctions – with lower equity indices and debased fiat currencies then emerging. Either way, households and consumers will feel the pinch, which will have political implicatio­ns down the road.

 ?? ??
 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Nigeria