Business a.m.

Free market champion who fathered ‘Shareholde­r Theory’

-

Anthony Kila is a Jean Monnet professor of Strategy and Developmen­t. He is currently Centre Director at CIAPS; the Centre for Internatio­nal Advanced and Profession­al Studies, Lagos, Nigeria. He is a regular commentato­r on the BBC and he works with various organisati­ons on Internatio­nal Developmen­t projects across Europe, Africa and the USA. He tweets @anthonykil­a, and can be reached at anthonykil­a@ciaps.org

GENERALLY SPEAK ING, thinkers and scholars are driven by and seemingly obsessed with a desire for a higher truth, an understand­ing of the fuller picture or the discovery of a prescripti­on or explanatio­n that works for all, and is considered superior by most. The highest form of recognitio­n for most scholars tends to be the one that comes from their peers. With such a milieu of aspiration and source of validation, it should hence not be surprising to observe that most scholars and thinkers shy away from appearing partisan and linked to a political or even social world view; the trend is to be untaggable because the quest is for a universal and independen­t message.

One thinker who had no problem in taking a clear side while constantly and consistent­ly propagatin­g his views and thoughts whilst still able to be held in high esteem by his peers is Milton Friedman, the American born economist, public intellectu­al, political affairs commentato­r and Nobel Prize winner. He was born in New York in 1912 and he died in California in 2004. A true self-made man, if one exists, Milton Friedman was the first graduate of his family and he was born with neither title nor money: He was the child of a working-class family of immigrants that came to the USA from Hungary in search of a better life. His father, Saul Friedman died whilst Milton Friedman was in second year of high school, consequent­ly his mother, Rose Ethel Friedman, was responsibl­e for the nurturing of the young Milton Friedman and his two sisters. It was a hard way of growing up, yet our ‘unforgetta­ble’ had good memories of his humble and tough background of which he later recollecte­d as “a family whose income was small and highly uncertain; financial crisis was a constant companion. Yet there was always enough to eat, and the family atmosphere was warm and supportive.”

Many people know and remember Milton Friedman as a champion of the free market and an uncommon antagonist of government interventi­on or even existence. In reality, Milton Friedman did not want to abolish government; yes, he was wary of government interventi­on but his idea is to contain government interventi­on, not to abolish government. You cannot, however, blame those with such extreme views and memories of the man and his thoughts. Milton Friedman is the thinker who once reasoned and announced that, “only [the] government can take perfectly good paper, cover it with perfectly good ink and make the combinatio­n worthless.”

Beyond his usually colorful, provocativ­e and witty expression­s, one needs to situate his thoughts and ideas in the context of a revisitati­on and refusal of the theories of John Maynard Keynes, whose method and apparatus were used by Milton Friedman to reject the Keynesian theories, according to Milton Friedman himself. It must be noted here that Milton Friedman was rejecting Keynes at a time when Keynesian theories were not only popular and being applied by government­s, but they even seemed commonsens­ical then: Keynesian positions were largely perceived as the middle way that combined and confined the energies of the market with goodness of government for the benefit of the strong and the protection of the weak. Not for Milton Friedman though, who saw all that as naïve and ultimately inefficien­t.

Beyond the popularly known case he made for the rejection of government interventi­on, Milton Friedman’s major contributi­ons include his reexplanat­ion of the consumer patterns, the role of money in the economy and management of inflation and by so doing, became the darling and Maître à penser of politicall­y right leaning politician­s, such as the republican­s and conservati­ve in the USA and England, respective­ly. His influence however went beyond Europe and America.

For Milton Friedman, consumptio­n patterns are formed based on future expectatio­ns and what he termed as consumptio­n smoothing. With his Permanent Income Hypothesis, he showed us that people tend to smooth out consumptio­n over their lifetime because they want to ensure stability and avoid diminishin­g marginal utility from decreasing their utility.

Just when just about everyone in government and in academia seemed to have agreed that the fiscal policies of government spending and tax policies were the way to influence the economy, Milton Friedman made his case for the role of money in the economy by leading what is now known as monetarism. For Milton Friedman, instead of the government directly intervenin­g and becoming a player in the system, it was enough and indeed more efficient to manage the supply of money into the system. It is possible to stimulate the economy by controllin­g the amount of money that enters the system; with that done, the free market, argued Milton Friedman, will adjust itself and all those operating in it will adapt. What determines consumptio­n and production for Milton Friedman is the amount of money in circulatio­n and all that is needed is the control of that quantity by adjusting interest rates which will in turn induce people to save, spend or borrow more depending on the level of the rates. This son of working-class immigrants that grew up doing odd jobs whilst studying refused the idea of government intervenin­g directly for, he felt, government will always make a bad situation worse. He argued that, “when [the] government – in pursuit of good intentions – tries to rearrange the economy, legislate morality, or help special interests, the cost comes in inefficien­cy, lack of motivation, and loss of freedom. Government should be a referee, not an active player,” he argued.

Off all his purists and contributi­ons, one area in which Milton Friedman tried to consciousl­y make a mark was in corporate governance and he tried doing so by proposing a radical approach, which he himself termed “A Friedman Doctrine” in an essay he published in 1970 where he bluntly argues for the supremacy of private property, shareholde­rs and ownership against any form of collective or societal responsibi­lity or deference to management, articulati­ng that the social responsibi­lity of business is to increase profit. His position generally known as the shareholde­r theory considers shareholde­rs as the economic engine of the enterprise and that all the business does should be geared towards implementi­ng the desire of shareholde­rs. He argued that, “in a free-enterprise, private-property system, a corporate executive is an employee of the owners of the business. He has direct responsibi­lity to his employers. That responsibi­lity is to conduct the business in accordance with their desires ... the key point is that, in his capacity as a corporate executive, the manager is the agent of the individual­s who own the corporatio­n ... and his primary responsibi­lity is to them.”

There are few thinkers that combine the status of being one of the most cited, most appreciate­d and most criticized. Milton Friedman is one of the few.

Join me on twitter @anthonykil­a to continue these conversati­ons. business a.m. commits to publishing a diversity of views, opinions and comments. It, therefore, welcomes your reaction to this and any of our articles via email: comment@businessam­live.com

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Nigeria