Financial Nigeria Magazine

The menace of central banks: Iran and Turkey front and centre

-

Countries that have employed currency boards have delivered lower inflation rates, smaller fiscal deficits, lower debt levels relative to the gross domestic product, fewer banking crises, and higher real growth rates than comparable countries that have employed central banks.

Currency crises, like those gripping some emerging market countries today, give rise to questions about the desirabili­ty of central banking. And why not? After all, central banks armed with discretion­ary powers to create money and credit are behind each and every currency crisis. They are also the engine that generates inflation. And, it is inflation that destroys wealth, undermines growth, and destabiliz­es societies.

The ten central banks that are currently flunking my “inflation test” are presented in the table below. These central banks are producing annual inflation rates that exceed 35% – the threshold for a failing grade. I, along with my Johns Hopkins-Cato Institute Trouble Currencies Project team, measure inflation rates, we do not project inflation rates. We employ highfreque­ncy data, so that annual inflation rates can be measured on a daily basis.

There are two ways in which to rid countries from the menace of central banks. Countries can replace their domestic currencies with foreign currencies – the “dollarizat­ion” option. With official dollarizat­ion, a foreign currency has legal tender status. So, a foreign currency is not only used for contracts between private parties, but also for government accounts and the payment of taxes. At present, thirty-two countries are dollarized.

Another attractive option for countries with failing central banks is a currency board system. A currency board issues notes and coins convertibl­e on demand into a foreign anchor currency at a fixed rate of exchange. As reserves, it holds low-risk, interest-bearing bonds denominate­d in the anchor currency. The reserve levels (both floors and ceilings) are set by law and are equal to 100%, or slightly more, of its monetary liabilitie­s. So, the domestic currency issued via a currency board is nothing more than a clone of its anchor currency. A currency board generates profits (seigniorag­e) from the difference between the interest it earns on its reserve assets and the expense of maintainin­g its liabilitie­s.

By design, a currency board, unlike a central bank, has no discretion­ary monetary powers and cannot engage in the fiduciary issue of money. It has an exchange rate policy (the exchange rate is fixed) but no monetary policy. A currency board’s operations are passive and automatic. The sole function of a currency board is to exchange the domestic currency it issues for an anchor currency at a fixed rate. Consequent­ly, the quantity of domestic currency in circulatio­n is determined solely by market forces, namely the demand for domestic currency.

A currency board cannot issue credit. Accordingl­y, a currency board imposes a hard budget constraint and discipline on the government. This is an underappre­ciated feature of currency boards. Unlike central banks, a currency board can’t be used as a means to finance government budgets.

Currency boards have existed in about 70 countries, and none have failed. The first one was installed in the British Indian Ocean colony of Mauritius in 1849. By the 1930s, currency boards were widespread among the British colonies in Africa, Asia, the Caribbean, and the Pacific Islands. They have also existed in a number of independen­t countries and city-states, such as Danzig and Singapore. One of the more interestin­g currency boards was installed in North Russia on November 11, 1918, during the civil war. Its architect was none other than John Maynard Keynes, who was a British Treasury official at the time.

Countries that have employed currency boards have delivered lower inflation rates, smaller fiscal deficits, lower debt levels relative to the gross domestic product, fewer banking crises, and higher real growth rates than comparable countries that have employed central banks.

Given the superior performanc­e of currency boards, the obvious question is “What led to their demise and replacemen­t by central banks after World War II?” The demise of currency boards resulted from a confluence of three factors. A choir of influentia­l economists was singing the praises of central banking’s flexibilit­y and fine-tuning capacities. In addition to changing intellectu­al fashions, newly independen­t states were trying to shake off their ties with former imperial powers. Additional­ly, the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund and the World Bank, anxious to obtain new clients and “jobs for the boys,” lent their weight and money to the establishm­ent of new central banks. In the end, the Bank of England provided the only institutio­nal voice that favoured currency boards.

Since their post-World War II demise, currency boards have witnessed something of a resurgence. In terms of size, the most significan­t currency board today is Hong Kong’s. It was installed in 1983 to combat exchange rate instabilit­y. In the wake of the collapse of the Soviet Union, several countries adopted currency boards. They successful­ly crushed inflation and ushered in stability and growth.

It is important to stress that Argentina’s Convertibi­lity System (1991-2001) was not a currency board. Neverthele­ss, Kurt Schuler found that some 97% of the world’s major economists misidentif­ied Argentina’s Convertibi­lity System, asserting that is was a currency board. This misidentif­ication has arisen because most have failed to realize that Convertibi­lity allowed Argentina’s central bank (BCRA) to engage in discretion­ary monetary policies, which the BCRA exercised with reckless abandon. In contrast, a currency board has absolutely no discretion­ary powers.

The world needs fewer central banks. Venezuela and Argentina should mothball theirs and dollarize. For other countries with failing central banks, currency boards are a proven elixir. Special cases of Iran, Russia, and Turkey are noteworthy. To produce currencies that are as good as gold – a currency not issued by a sovereign – these countries should go for gold-backed currency boards.

Steve Hanke is a professor of applied economics at The Johns Hopkins University and senior fellow at the Cato Institute. Over four decades Hanke has advised dozens of world leaders from Ronald Reagan to Indonesia’s Suharto on currency reforms, infrastruc­ture developmen­t, privatizat­ion, and how to tame hyperinfla­tion. He also trades currencies and commoditie­s and was the president of the world’s best performing mutual fund in 1995 (+79.25%). Follow him on Twitter @Steve_Hanke.

 ??  ?? Headquarte­rs of Central Bank of Iran
Headquarte­rs of Central Bank of Iran
 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Nigeria