Financial Nigeria Magazine

What next for unconventi­onal monetary policies?

-

Although interest-rate cuts and central-bank asset purchases were highly effective in resolving the 2008 financial crisis, they have proved utterly disappoint­ing in the years since. At this stage, it should be clear that the sustained weakness of private-sector investment is not a problem central bankers can fix on their own.

The Bank for Internatio­nal Settlement­s (BIS), the central bankers' club in Basel, Switzerlan­d, recently conducted an indepth evaluation of the unconventi­onal monetary policies that have become the norm in many countries since the 2008 financial crisis. It should come as no surprise that the resulting report, compiled by a committee of central bankers reviewing their own past performanc­e, finds little to fault. That is fine; the financial system was saved, after all. But a more important question is whether, and to what extent, unconventi­onal policies remain relevant in the post-crisis world.

Back in 2008, the primary task for policymake­rs was to prevent the financial sector from collapsing and stabilize the economy. Convention­al policies proved insufficie­nt, and it became clear that other measures were needed to address the financial meltdown directly. Chief among these was quantitati­ve easing, in which the central bank buys up assets in order to inject liquidity into the financial system.

In November 2008, at the height of the crisis, the US Federal Reserve started purchasing securities in the then-frozen mortgage market. QE1, as it came to be known, was highly successful: mortgage lending soon resumed, supporting the crippled housing market, and many borrowers were able to refinance their loans at much lower interest rates.

The QE1 purchases might have been unusual, but they were not “unconventi­onal.” Walter Bagehot, the storied editor of The Economist, pointed out over a century ago that it was the duty of central banks to prop up collapsing financial sectors. Central banks have been stepping in and leveraging their balance sheets in times of crisis ever since. When QE1 began, Lehman Brothers was bankrupt, the insurance giant AIG had been bailed out, and the money market had been given a government guarantee. Against that backdrop, QE1 was just another rescue measure among many throughout Western economic history.

The unanimous view is that QE1 and central banks' other immediate measures were successful. But once the financial system had been saved, monetary policymake­rs started confrontin­g an entirely different challenge. Despite near-zero interest rates, the post-crisis recovery was decidedly lackluster.

So, QE continued, but with a new operationa­l objective: to give monetary policy more traction by lowering the long end of the yield curve. With this objective in mind, several central banks pushed interest rates into negative territory. And through “forward guidance” announceme­nts that interest rates would be kept “low for long” – central bankers assured markets that the era of cheap funding would continue.

For all of the boldness of these initiative­s, the results were disappoint­ing. US bank lending fell after QE1 began, and didn't recover its precrisis peak until more than three years later. In Europe and the United Kingdom, bank lending was even less responsive. Japan, the country with the longest experience of QE, remains mired in slow growth and below-target inflation to this day.

Negative interest rates often seemed to be aimed mainly at achieving a more competitiv­e exchange rate, which might well have been criticized as a “beggar thy neighbour” policy. Forward guidance, meanwhile, just confused things: market participan­ts became more focused on the next round of “guidance” than on the economy's prospects, and often overreacte­d to the wording of the central bank's latest pronouncem­ent, as in the case of the 2013 “taper tantrum.”

Despite the mediocre performanc­e of unconventi­onal monetary policies throughout the recovery phase, the BIS

report concludes that the benefits outweighed the adverse side effects. It goes on to argue that such policies should become a standard monetarypo­licy tool. The unconventi­onal should become routine.

Yet that wouldn't resolve the central conundrum of the post-crisis period. Why didn't extremely loose monetarypo­licy conditions have more of an impact? The BIS report itself offers a clue when it argues that unconventi­onal monetary policies would be more effective if accompanie­d by other policies, notably fiscal expansion.

During the post-2010 period, fiscal austerity prevailed around the world, which was completely out of balance with the super-expansiona­ry monetary conditions. True, many government­s pursued fiscal stimulus immediatel­y following the 2008 crash, and these measures were endorsed by the G20 in London in 2009. But by 2010, the European periphery was in crisis and fears of rising public debt ushered in broad fiscal retrenchme­nt. In the five years to 2015, the United States reduced its deficit by 5% of GDP. That alone is enough to explain why the recovery was so weak.

But it doesn't explain why near-zero interest rates have had so little effect on private-sector investment. As the economist Paul Samuelson once reportedly quipped, if real (inflationa­djusted) interest rates were zero and expected to remain so, it would be profitable to flatten the Rocky Mountains just to reduce transporta­tion costs. With borrowing costs so low for so long, why has there not been an explosion of profitable projects and investment­s?

A number of answers have been suggested, from Lawrence H. Summers's contention that we are experienci­ng “secular stagnation,” to the argument that short-termism has short-circuited corporate managers' decision-making. Perhaps US President Donald Trump's trade war has contribute­d confidence-sapping uncertaint­y. Or maybe all of the best investment projects are in the nonmarket public sector, where deficit

fears have prevented them from being realized.

Whatever the answer, it is doubtful that pushing harder on monetary policy – with lower (perhaps negative) interest rates and the full panoply of unconventi­onal policies – would lead to much additional investment. Moreover, unconventi­onal policies can distort financial prices, resulting in poor assessment­s, resource misallocat­ions, and arbitrary reallocati­ons of wealth.

In the short term, then, the BIS report's oblique and subtle message should be heeded: the strenuous efforts of monetary policies over the past decade need to be supplement­ed by fiscal expansion, especially if the global economy is slowing. But in the longer term, we need a better understand­ing of why private-sector investment has lost its mojo.

Stephen Grenville, a former deputy governor of the Reserve Bank of Australia, is a non-resident fellow at the Lowy Institute in Sydney. Copyright: Project Syndicate

 ??  ?? Stephen Grenville
Stephen Grenville
 ??  ?? U.S. Federal Reserve Bank headquarte­rs in Washington, D.C.
U.S. Federal Reserve Bank headquarte­rs in Washington, D.C.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Nigeria