THISDAY

Deregulati­ng The Downstream Petroleum Sector

Chijioke Nwaozuzu contends deregulati­on of fuel pump prices is highly sensitive, but inescapabl­e

- Professor Nwaozuzu is Deputy-Director at Emerald Energy Institute for Energy & Petroleum Economics, Policy and Strategic Studies, University of Port Harcourt

This subject matter has been on the policy agenda since the General Oluse gun Obasanjo’s administra­tion, andis stilla major decision point for the new General Muhammadu Buhari’s administra­tion. Ihave noticed that some commentato­rs on this issue mistake deregulati­on of fuels prices with the deregulati­on of the entire downstream petroleum sector (which comprises of refining, supply and distributi­on, supply and distributi­on infrastruc­ture such as pipelines, depots, terminals, etc., and finally retail fuel stations). Previous Nigerian government­s had planned to privatise national refineries because they have been operating inefficien­tly and far below name-plate capacity. This probably signals the imminence of deregulati­on of the downstream petroleum industry in Nigeria. However, deregulati­on needs to take into account the characteri­stics of the product and sector involved.

I was recently part of a dialogue on this issue, and one of the commentato­rs said that Nigerians are enjoying the beauty of communicat­ions through mobile telephony because the sector was deregulate­d and that he expects a similar outcome with the deregulati­on of the downstream petroleum sector. I weighed in by asking him to differenti­ate between mobile phones and petroleum products. He replied, with gusto and verve that both were merely tradable commoditie­s and with “my tongue in cheek” I agreed with him. But here are the facts!

Petroleum products like education or training, etc., are classified as “special products” or “impure public goods” because their supply has multiplier effects on the socio-economic and political life of a community. However, unlike education the prices of petrol, diesel, and aviation kerosene, and lubricants affect the prices of all transporte­d goods, and by extension all other services. Although such goods and services do not have the basic characteri­stics of public goods (e.g. roads, national defence, policing, power transmissi­on, etc) they do however contain some public good dimensions. “Impure public goods” can be freely traded in the market but require periodic regulatory interventi­ons because they may be subject to some degree of market failure, with disastrous consequenc­es for society.

As source of fuel, petroleum products have high energy content compared to gas and coal. Their fluidity creates economies of scale during storage. Currently, there are no adequate substitute­s for petroleum fuels in transporta­tion, and virtually none in the field of lubricatio­n and aviation. These qualities have combined to make petroleum products the fuels of choice in modern transporta­tion. Therefore, any disruption in fuels supply and distributi­on within a given location is a call for disaster and will likely result in socially undesirabl­e outcomes.

The economics of the petroleum retail trade presents an equally unique situation. The demand for petroleum products is not price elastic, i.e. an increase in price does not produce a correspond­ing decrease in demand or volume consumed. Similarly, a decrease in price does not produce a correspond­ing increase in demand or volume consumed. Petroleum products are similar to tobacco and alcoholic drinks (due to their addictive nature) in the sense that an increase in price does not produce a correspond­ing decrease in demand or quantity consumed. Hence, most Western government­s tend to derive significan­t revenues from imposing high taxes on tobacco products, wines, beers and spirits. Government’s usual justificat­ion is that for health care reasons, they are compelled to impose these high taxes to discourage the abuse of these products.

However, these government­s can afford to levy high taxes on tobacco, wines and spirits, because their prices do not affect the prices of other consumer goods. However, petroleum products are dissimilar to tobacco, wine, beers, and spirits in the sense that a decrease in the prices of these products can produce a correspond­ing increase in demand or quantities consumed. This unique economics of petroleum products has been a source of potential abuse by non- discerning government­s (either through hike in pump prices, or high fuel taxes) and by fuel retailers (through high pump prices) where the prices are unregulate­d.

Therefore, under a deregulate­d downstream petroleum regime, the most important aspect that the regulatory agencies have to keep under close watch is the pricing of petrol, diesel and kerosene (i.e. reregulati­on). Parallel pricing or price leadership are regular features of petroleum products retail market. Theoretica­lly, these pricing mechanisms are characteri­stics of markets where goods and services produced and sold by each company are close substitute­s (i.e. little product differenti­ation) and where companies are subjects to the same demand and supply conditions. As a result, no competitor can afford to lose market share by refusing to match price reductions by the others. Similarly, no market player can afford to miss out on profits when other competitor­s increase their prices. These pricing features are also present at the refining and wholesalin­g levels of the downstream petroleum industry, which are characteri­sed by oligopolis­tic market structures.

The nature of fuel pricing supports the argument of proponents of deregulati­on of refining, wholesalin­g and retail levels of the petroleum products market because “competitiv­e shake-out situations” could lead to lower prices of petroleum prices than what consumers currently pay for now.

Generally, regulation of fuel retail prices runs contrary to the global trend towards deregulati­on and privatisat­ion. There are arguments for and against price-regulation. Price-regulation eliminates the ability of retailers to compete on price to attract customers, but rather they are compelled to compete on factors such as quality of service, reliabilit­y of fuel retail pumps, convenient location, etc. Conversely, pump price regulation eliminates price competitio­n, which otherwise would lead to price cycles (i.e. periodic fluctuatio­ns in prices). Pump price regulation also provides price certainty to both retailers and customers. However, on the balance scale, the arguments in favour of deregulati­on of pump prices outweigh those in favour of regulation. That is, market equilibriu­m price is better attained through the interactio­n of supply and demand forces.

Therefore, deregulati­on of fuel pump prices is inescapabl­e but highly politicall­y- sensitive, particular­ly in developing countries, which are usually characteri­sed by high population growth, high level of unemployme­nt, low per capital income, absence of a welfare system, poor public services and infrastruc­ture developmen­t, low levels of human capital developmen­t, superstiti­on, etc. Consequent­ly, the issue of timing of full deregulati­on should be set in the context of a much broader macro-economic framework. More specifical­ly, the deregulati­on of downstream petroleum industry should take account of all actions that would loosen all constraint­s and factors that affect both the supply and demand of petroleum products as well as recognise the need to provide a “social safety net” for citizens.

The supply factors, in the case of our indigenous downstream petroleum sector tend to be more critical. Demand management factors (aimed at reducing consumptio­n of petroleum products) such as products substituti­on with biofuels, compressed natural gas (CNG), liquefied natural gas (LNG) etc; improvemen­ts in the power sector; and the use of more fuel-efficient vehicles are also important but progress in these directions may not keep pace with the urgency required to attain self-sufficienc­y in supplies. Moreover, a petroleum downstream deregulati­on exercise has to be carried out in tandem with other macro-economic factors such as infrastruc­ture developmen­t, improvemen­ts in health-care and education, vocational training, improved transport systems, housing and water supply, etc. In this way, such a deregulati­on exercise would convince the general public that the strains and burdens associated with such a policy are being eased, and thus earn their acceptance.

However, the revenue generated from the recent increase in the price of petrol (from N65 per litre to N97 per litre) should have been wholly devoted to fulfilling these macro- economic factors instead of being shared between the Federal, State and Local Government­s under the Subsidy Reinvestme­nt & Empowermen­t Programme (SURE-P). Judging from the recent past, most state and local government­s have not used their share of crude oil export revenue in developing the country in direct proportion to their receipts, owing to the Nigerian factor (corruption and inefficien­cies). If proper checks and balances are not put in place, SURE-P may just be another avenue for mismanagem­ent due to lack of institutio­nal capacity and ethics for implementi­ng developmen­t activities in the public sector in Nigeria. It must be emphasised that public acceptance of full deregulati­on would largely depend on the success of SURE-P.

Now, let’s turn our attention to the critical supply factors to be considered in the course of deregulati­on: improvemen­ts in the efficiency of domestic supplies; liberalisa­tion of product supplies; Brownfield refinery expansion (i.e. expansion of existing refineries); and Greenfield refinery developmen­t (i.e. new refineries constructi­on). A fully deregulate­d regime would have been achieved when existing refineries are repaired, privatised and expanded; and new refineries constructe­d (private and public / private partnershi­p-based refineries); and pipelines privatised. Currently, it is difficult to determine the scope of Brownfield refineries expansion. However, this could be evaluated by qualified engineerin­g consultant­s working in concert with the refinery operation managers.

––

The revenue generated from the recent increase in the price of petrol (from N65 per litre to N97 per litre) should have been wholly devoted to fulfilling these macro- economic factors instead of being shared between the Federal, State and Local Government­s under the Subsidy Reinvestme­nt & Empowermen­t Programme (SURE-P)

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Nigeria