Oman Daily Observer

Why have inflation forecasts been so wrong?

- Willem H. Buiter

Last year, following the Great Inflation of 2021-22, central banks, leading academics, and internatio­nal institutio­ns issued a smattering of postmortem­s. Yet even before the ink was dry on their analyses, inflation forecasts were being revised down almost as fast as they had been revised up during the two preceding years.

For example, in June 2023, the US Federal Reserve’s median projection for core year-on-year personalco­nsumption-expenditur­es inflation (excluding food and energy prices) in the fourth quarter was 3.9 per cent, with the Federal Open Market Committee’s projection­s ranging from 3.6 per cent to 4.5 per cent. In the event, it was 3.2 per cent.

Before addressing what forecaster­s are missing, two clarificat­ions are in order. First, central banks’ inflation forecasts are no worse, and may be somewhat better, than private-sector forecasts, on average – which is what one would expect, given that they tend to have better access to data and more expertise. Second, inflation forecasts have not obviously gotten worse. Yes, the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund, among others, has noted that inflation forecast errors were 2.5 and five times larger for 2021 and 2022, respective­ly, than the average for 2010-19. But the levels of annual inflation in 2021 and 2022 were 1.3 and 2.5 times larger than the 2010-19 average, and the changes in annual inflation rates were 2.6 and 7.1 times larger.

The benign interpreta­tion is that the shocks got bigger, not that inflation forecastin­g became less competent. But an obvious rejoinder is that forecasts don’t particular­ly matter when the variable being forecast doesn’t change much. We still need to know why forecasts continue to miss the mark. Two factors are now well-documented. First, forecasts underestim­ated the demand impact of massive monetary and fiscal easing, alongside high spending multiplier­s associated with significan­t pandemic-related transfers to households. Second, major demand stimulus hit just as supply chains were under major, unexpected strain, owing first to the pandemic and then to Russia’s war on Ukraine. Shocks are by definition difficult to predict, and they were particular­ly large in 2020-22. But the forecasts also had a more fundamenta­l flaw: they lacked realistic representa­tions of price and wage setting. Large shocks differ from small shocks in that they change key features of the transmissi­on mechanism. For example, firms tend to change prices more frequently when faced with large shocks. According to the Fed, during the second half of 2021 and again during the second half of 2022, firms updated prices twice as often as they did before the pandemic.

Large shocks may well have been the reason. But firms also find it more straightfo­rward to raise prices when others are already doing so, and the combined pandemic and energy shocks probably were an effective coordinati­on device for price increases. Wage setting is different from price setting. According to a 2009 European Central Bank study, firms tend to change wages about one-third less frequently than prices. Wage growth did pick up throughout 2021-22 as workers quit at record rates (a trend that closely tracked wage pressure). But the models underestim­ated how long it would take for tight labour markets and large price increases to feed into wage setting. Those delays prolonged the underlying inflationa­ry impulse without necessaril­y magnifying it in a cumulative sense. Importantl­y, many of the factors that pushed up priceswere“one-off”adjustment­s in response to supply and demand shocks. They called for more significan­t relative price changes than would have been the case if there had been a shock to trend inflation driven by persistent­ly excessive aggregate demand. This was most evident in the major energy-price shock in 2022. It was exactly that: a relative price shock that partly reversed in 2023. Similar dynamics played out in the prices of goods that were closely tied to energy prices or were immediatel­y affected by major supply-chain strains. These, too, reversed – as we saw with car prices and container freight rates. There is a vibrant debate about whether firms abnormally raised their profit margins in recent years. A recent Fed study finds that nonfinanci­al corporate profits rose to 19 per cent over gross value-added in the second quarter of 2021, up from 13 per cent in the fourth quarter of 2019. But once prices have risen and profit margins are high, they are less – not more –likely to rise further than before the large price adjustment­s. Normalisin­g energy prices, supply chains, and profit margins all contribute­d to the fasterthan-expected decline in inflation in the second half of 2023. The Great Inflation will be as transforma­tional for central banks’ models as the 2008 financial crisis was. Back then, the models were adapted to include a more realistic mapping of financial impacts. Now, we need a more realistic treatment of price and wage setting. Specifical­ly, three changes are in order. Most importantl­y, understand­ing inflation requires analysis at the sectoral or subsectora­l level, ideally in a way that also reflects supply-chain linkages. This will make forecasts even more complex, but there is no way around it. Considerin­g disaggrega­ted data is essential to identifyin­g, and disentangl­ing, the relevant changes in supply and demand and their persistenc­e. Individual sectors sometimes significan­tly affect aggregate inflation, with house prices in the US being a prominent example.

Second, forecasts should account for the level (or size) of shocks to capture non-linearitie­s, especially for profit mark-ups. And lastly, forecasts should regularly reexamine changes in circumstan­ces and assumption­s. During the Great Inflation, important changes in the US included the major boost to aggregate demand (from monetised fiscal transfers to households); the higher frequency of price adjustment­s, given the size of the combined supply and demand shock; and the high number of recently refinanced mortgages that locked in low rates.

Fed Chair Jerome Powell, paraphrasi­ng Winston Churchill, recently called forecaster­s “a humble lot – with much to be humble about.” Though they will have learned many useful lessons from the Great Inflation of 2021-22, remaining humble may be the best way to avoid being humbled again.

The writer is a former chief economist at Citibank and former member of the Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England, is an independen­t economic adviser

The writer is an independen­t strategist and economist, is a former chief currency strategist, global head of foreignexc­hange analysis, and head of global macroecono­mics at Citigroup

 ?? ??
 ?? ?? The IMF has noted that inflation forecast errors were 2.5 and five times larger for 2021 and 2022 respective­ly.
The IMF has noted that inflation forecast errors were 2.5 and five times larger for 2021 and 2022 respective­ly.
 ?? ?? Ebrahim Rahbari
Ebrahim Rahbari

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Oman