The Pak Banker

The cost of stability

-

IN another testament to how unrooted and repetitive Pakistani politics can be, major talking points for the media in recent months have been rumours of in-house change, ruling coalition factionali­sm, deals and no deals, and other artefacts of elite intrigue. No one can draw a complete picture of the actors involved; no one fully knows who is staving off or applying pressure; no one knows what the exact contents of any purported deal may be. And yet shadowy intrigue and its related discourse are what pass of as mainstream politics here. This is a country in which the idea of constant conspiracy is not only a framework for explanatio­n, but also a force that actually destabilis­es politics itself.

So what is the cost of maintainin­g at least the appearance of political stability in Pakistan? The current dispensati­on provides an interestin­g case study to test through one major theory. The idea just prior to the 2018 election was that stability is a product of a few key actors being on the same page. This included, principall­y, the military high command and the ruling party leadership, with the judiciary providing passive consent.

This particular theory was grounded in several things, with the most obvious being what had happened with the last government (or for that matter, most other civilian government­s in Pakistan's political history). The theory is that clarity of mandate, a firm and accepted hierarchy between the two main actors, and a shared vision of how to proceed with the nuts and bolts of domestic and foreign policy would be enough to keep the ship steady.

This theory is seductive on paper for a number of reasons. Most visibly, it eliminates the biggest source of political instabilit­y (and its underlying intrigue) by ensuring that the most powerful and wellresour­ced political actor - the military - has ownership of the process. As long as it stays firm - and why wouldn't it in a scenario where it gets to call all the major shots - the ship remains steady.

Go back to every period of apparent political stability in the country and you'll see how a layer of patronage was needed to sustain it.

But in practice, this theory, and much of our convention­al analysis that feeds into it, tends to underplay the fact that political outcomes are at least partially contingent on a host of other actors as well. Most prominentl­y, these include elected politician­s both in and outside government, as well as the bureaucrac­y.

Electoral legitimacy has mostly been a surface-level concern for parties and government­s in Pakistan. This has been true for nearly every type of ruling arrangemen­t since 1970. But for whatever reason elections continue to exist. Whether under military regimes, or under nominally democratic ones, elections have been hard to shake off; and they seem to produce their own sources of stability and instabilit­y.

Party leaders need elected politician­s to provide them with a veneer of legitimacy and to form a government. They need elected politician­s from other parties to pass legislatio­n. Simultaneo­usly, elected politician­s need the government (and its considerab­le material and administra­tive resources) to stay elected. For all the machinatio­ns in the world, for all the experiment­s in hybrid design, for all the same-page-ism, this reality is hard to shake off.

Now, let's turn back to events from recent weeks: a few elected politician­s grumbling about a lack of resources in

Punjab; a few of them doing the same in KP. One set in Balochista­n trying to engineer a change in government, another in Punjab trying to change the chief minister. And a media accustomed to reporting on political intrigue and instabilit­y for its eyeballs having a field day.

From a functional perspectiv­e, politician­s - especially rural ones - asking for the coffers to free up so they can direct resources to their constituen­cy is a conflictin­g feature of Pakistani politics. It's obvious this money is going to be used to sustain and secure their own privilege through patronage. But holding back the pork sets the wheels of intrigue in motion, which produces its own instabilit­y. Go back to every period of apparent political stability in the country (1960s, 1980s, early 2000s) and you'll see how a layer of patronage - mostly in the shape of curated local and provincial government­s - was needed to sustain it.

This is the dilemma that the current dispensati­on faces. Its leadership promises technocrat­ic government with civilmilit­ary congruence, but undergirdi­ng one part of the equation are elected politician­s. It repeatedly promised programmat­ic use of state resources (in a bid to fight discretion) but it has no strength to fight off the factionali­sm. And it promised fiscal prudence and political stability (and desperatel­y needs both) to ride out a painful period of macroecono­mic stabilisat­ion, but it is unclear whether it has the numbers and discipline to see through it.

If the logic of electoral survival throws same page-ism and its promised stability into disarray at one level, it also reveals the hollowness of Pakistan's political parties. Imran Khan - the leader of the party that promises reform - is popular with sections of the electorate. But it is still unclear just how powerful (and how much sway) he has over the people elected by that electorate.

And to complicate matters further, it seems that the party has no organised way - short of upending the entire political system - of sidesteppi­ng or replacing the elected representa­tives that prop up its central and provincial government­s.

At some point, a functional decision will be made (if it hasn't already), as has been the case in a number of occasions in the past. The decision will entail loosening the coffers, placing preferred individual­s in desired positions, and giving in to the demands of coalition partners.

 ??  ??
 ??  ?? The idea just prior to the 2018
The idea just prior to the 2018

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Pakistan