Business World

THE ECONOMIC COST OF FEDERALISM COLLABORAT­ION, NOT COMPETITIO­N

In the language of economics, federalism will result in zero-sum game with one region’s gain becoming another’s loss.

- NICETO S. POBLADOR

One of the most frequently mentioned reasons for adopting a federal form of government in the Philippine­s is to promote competitio­n among the states. It is a generally accepted argument that this will be beneficial to society as a whole. This position rests on the traditiona­l textbook assumption that allowing firms to compete among themselves in pursuit of their individual profit objectives will result in lower prices and better quality products for consumers and will therefore yield maximum benefits for society as a whole.

The question we pose here is whether this same argument applies to competitio­n among the states that will comprise Philippine society.

We believe not. A key proposal of those who advocate federalism in the Philippine­s is to encourage the different states to compete among themselves in pursuit of their respective economic objectives with a minimum of interferen­ce from a central authority to direct their actions.

We contend that competitio­n among the different regions of the country will have deleteriou­s effects on the welfare of society as a whole, and in the long run on their own individual well-being as well.

In the context of the issue at hand, competitio­n takes two forms: competitio­n for foreign markets and competitio­n for common resources.

The different regions and provinces of the Philippine­s sell their products and services to essentiall­y the same countries. This is true for most of our manufactur­es, our services, and our agricultur­al, fisheries and mineral exports, and certainly for our world-renown tourist spots.

Consider competitio­n in tourism, a major dollar earner for the country.

Monthly tourist arrivals in the Philippine­s reached over 550,000 in December 2015, a figure which continues to rise. These visitors came mostly from South Korea ( 136,156 arrivals in December 2015), the US ( 87,106), Japan (42,903), Australia (32,768) and Canada (23,264).

We maintain that competing for foreign visitors, while potentiall­y beneficial to a particular region or tourist destinatio­n, may be detrimenta­l to others. Every additional dollar earned by one part of the country through active promotiona­l activities will most likely result in one dollar less income elsewhere. Prospectiv­e tourists with fixed budgets and limited time who are induced to visit El Nido may decide to cancel their planned visit to Boracay. One region’s gain is another’s loss.

Having a larger slice of a given tourism pie means that a smaller portion of the pie will be available to other tourist destinatio­ns in the country. In the language of economics, this strategy is a zerosum game. Essentiall­y the same argument applies to competitio­n for foreign markets in general, especially in agricultur­al, fisheries, forestry and mineral commoditie­s.

A preferred approach is to engage in joint promotiona­l activities intended to sell the country as a whole — in other words, attempt to create a larger tourism pie for all to share. This requires collaborat­ion, not competitio­n.

TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS

The country is rich in resources much of which are shared by many parts of the country. These common resources include most of our forestry, mineral and marine resources. Our entire ecosystem is a resource that is common to all. These resources, along with our common cultural heritage and historical roots, are collective­ly referred to as “the commons.” They are available to all of society and not allocable to its components for their exclusive use.

The free access to the commons typically results in overuse and their eventual depletion and degradatio­n. Unrestrain­ed competitio­n for the commons among the different regions of the country results in what is known as a “negative sum game.”

Here, everybody loses. It calls to reason that the most appropriat­e strategy is a joint endeavor among all regions and political subdivisio­ns of the country to preserve and develop our common resources.

In both competitio­n for our common markets and competitio­n for our shared resources, collaborat­ion, not competitio­n, should be encouraged. Such collaborat­ion is less feasible under a federal regime.

THE FIX

We do realize that there is a need to empower the different

political subdivisio­ns, and to give them the autonomy to independen­tly pursue their peculiar economic, political, social and cultural interests. To ensure that these individual actions are not taken at the expense of the interest society, appropriat­e governance mechanisms and control systems should be put in place. This is most effectivel­y achieved in a unitary system of government.

Having said all these, we believe that establishi­ng a federal system of government for the Philippine­s is not an appropriat­e course of action. It is sufficient that we reform and fine-tune the unitary system that is currently in place in the light of our accumulate­d experience with it in order to enhance the well-being of the country, and at the same time preserve the unique cultural and social identities of the different regions that comprise our diverse society.

Changing the system outright to a federal one is an extremely disruptive strategy and will most certainly lead to undesirabl­e consequenc­es.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Philippines