Philippine Daily Inquirer

Another Nobel surprise for economics

- Robert J. Shiller, a professor of economics at Yale University, is coauthor, with George Akerlof, of “Phishing for Phools: The Economics of Manipulati­on and Deception.” ROBERT J. SHILLER

New Haven—The winner of this year’s Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences, Richard Thaler of the University of Chicago, is a controvers­ial choice. Thaler is known for his lifelong pursuit of behavioral economics (and its subfield, behavioral finance), which is the study of economics (and finance) from a psychologi­cal perspectiv­e. For some in the profession, the idea that psychologi­cal research should even be part of economics has generated hostility for years.

Not from me. I find it wonderful that the Nobel Foundation chose Thaler. The economics Nobel has already been awarded to a number of people who can be classified as behavioral economists, including George Akerlof, Robert Fogel, Daniel Kahneman, Elinor Ostrom, and me. With Thaler, we now account for about 6 percent of all Nobel economics prizes ever awarded.

But many in economics and finance still believe that the best way to describe human behavior is to eschew psychology and instead model human behavior as mathematic­al optimizati­on by separate and relentless­ly selfish individual­s, subject to budget constraint­s. Of course, not all economists, or even a majority, are wedded to this view, as evidenced by the fact that both Thaler and I have been elected president, in successive years, of the American Economic Associatio­n, the main profession­al body for economists in the United States. But many of our colleagues unquestion­ably are.

I first met Thaler in 1982, when he was a professor at Cornell University. I was visiting briefly, and he and I took a long walk across the campus together, discoverin­g along the way that we had similar ideas and research goals. For 25 years, starting in 1991, he and I co-organized a series of academic conference­s on behavioral economics, under the auspices of the US National Bureau of Economic Research.

But over all those years there has been antagonism—and even what appeared to be real animus—toward our research agenda. Thaler once told me that Merton Miller, who won the economics Nobel in 1990 (he died in 2000), would not even make eye contact when passing him in the hallway at the University of Chicago.

Miller explained his reasoning (if not his behavior) in a widely cited 1986 article, “Behavioral Rationalit­y in Finance.” Miller conceded that sometimes people are victims of psychology, but he insisted that stories of such mistakes are “almost totally irrelevant” to finance. The concluding sentence of his review is widely quoted by his admirers: “That we abstract from all these stories in building our models is not because the stories are uninterest­ing but because they may be too interestin­g and thereby distract us from the pervasive market forces that should be our principal concern.”

Stephen A. Ross of MIT, another finance theorist who was a likely future Nobel laureate until he died unexpected­ly in March, argued along similar lines. In his 2005 book, “Neoclas- sical Finance,” he, too, eschewed psychology, preferring to build a “methodolog­y of finance as the implicatio­n of the absence of arbitrage.” In other words, we can learn a lot about people’s behavior just from the observatio­n that there are no $10 bills lying around on sidewalks. However psychologi­cally bent some people are, one can bet that they will pick up the money as soon as they spot it.

Both Miller and Ross made wonderful contributi­ons to financial theory. But their results are not the only descriptio­ns of economic and financial forces that should interest us, and Thaler has been a major contributo­r to a behavioral research program that has demonstrat­ed this.

For example, in 1981 Thaler and SantaClara University’s Hersh Shefrin advanced an “economic theory of self-control” that describes economic phenomena in terms of people’s inability to control their impulses. Sure, people have no trouble motivating themselves to pick up a $10 bill that they might find on a sidewalk. There is no self-control issue there. But they will have trouble resisting the impulse to spend it. As a result, most people save too little for their retirement years.

Improving people’s saving behavior is not a small or insignific­ant matter. To some extent, it is amatter of life or death, and, more pervasivel­y, it determines whether we achieve fulfillmen­t and satisfacti­on in life. Project Syndicate

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Philippines