The Philippine Star

Contractua­lization and the larger issue of employment and poverty reduction

- GERARDO P. SICAT

The Department of Labor and Employment (DOLE) has finally signed off on the “endo” problem with Department Order No. 174.

The outcome of the order will likely lead to more unemployme­nt, some early confusion, and likely more dissatisfa­ction among stakeholde­rs. The worst outcome is for labor – the unskilled and the unemployed and underemplo­yed.

Endo ends, but contractua­lization continues. The new department order declares that the practice of “labor-only” contractin­g in which an agency recruits or supplies workers to perform a job or work, is prohibited. In the same breadth, however, it recognizes that some forms of labor contractin­g need to continue.

As a result, large companies serving the domestic market that have relied on some degree of labor contractin­g will continue with practices of labor hiring that they have with sub-contractor­s.

Also, many foreign direct investment­s operating especially in the industrial export sector will continue with their hiring practices with the help of labor contractor­s.

Those allowed to engage in labor contractin­g have been required to raise their capitaliza­tion. The order raises the financial requiremen­t to qualify as a service contractor.

In the same order, however, it allows the contractin­g and subcontrac­ting of labor services under specific conditions in which labor standards are observed and where the contractor has the ability to perform the job of subcontrac­ting the labor activity.

Reactions of stake-holders. The government, through DOLE and its secretary, Silvestre Bello, undertook a difficult and almost impossible task of reconcilin­g the conflictin­g demands of various stakeholde­rs.

Organized labor groups wanted it to end contractua­lization to force enterprise­s to hire workers for longer term periods. Many labor supporters and sympathize­rs are also critical of the order. They see it as a continuati­on of the same contractua­lization practices, even with the terminatio­n of “endo”.

Business enterprise­s find labor costs to be too high in relation to productivi­ty. A major reason is the high labor standards that have accumulate­d through the years of rising labor welfare legislatio­n – from minimum wages, pension deductions, to vacation leaves to 13th month pay. Many local businesses are apprehensi­ve that shoulderin­g the costs of regulariza­tion of employees would result to less hirings and/or retrenchme­nts.

Foreign investor groups already operating in the country are less bothered. As long as they can continue to hire their labor force, they are compliant with the changes.

The labor contractin­g that many foreign investors have been undertakin­g would continue without much disturbanc­e. Moreover, their pay structures are, in general, able to deal with the cost of hiring labor which, from their viewpoint, remains affordable.

Of course, the foreign direct investment­s the country attracts depends on the choices about costs that the investors prefer and the industry they are in. Many investors in the garments industry are not present in the country, but semiconduc­tor assemblers are plentiful. Foreign investment­s that depend on much lower labor costs would be squeezed somewhat harder.

Among local enterprise­s that do business mainly in the local economy, there is great sensitivit­y to the new policy. Some of the businesses are very sensitive to the cost of labor and the hiring practices that they have developed over time.

In general, many of the larger domestic enterprise­s serving the local market would survive some of the changes in the labor policy.

This is not the case with small enterprise­s. Will they survive a change in their framework, or will it mean their demise into the informal sector of the economy?

Many small and medium scale domestic enterprise­s will face a rising cost of hiring labor. Those unable to adjust to these circumstan­ces would simply have to dispense with additional hirings or evaporate into informalit­y.

In general, the worse hit among the stakeholde­rs is the worker who could be forced out of a job.

Our hope is to improve labor and industrial policies. Our labor market policies have tilted more and more toward worker protection and safeguardi­ng of income rather than on creating employment. The result of this bias has been to raise the cost of labor hiring within the economy to the great detriment of labor.

Other countries have avoided our problem by choosing the opposite approach. They did not focus on labor protection and income enhancemen­ts and in periodic government interventi­ons in behalf of labor.

The solution of the contractua­lization issue mainly retained the importance of continued contractua­lization, but it did not touch on improving the labor market policies by making them more flexible.

The problem of creating employment depends on (1) more investment­s and (2) improvemen­t of policies that open the way for investment­s that were difficult to materializ­e before. This means liberaliza­tion of policies, including those that might improve and make labor policies more flexible.

The government has not yet made any progress in liberalizi­ng provisions for removing the economic restrictio­ns on foreign direct investment­s in the constituti­on despite its plan to do so. There is no progress on this point in the discussion­s on constituti­onal amendments.

There have been no major changes in BOI policies concerning the improvemen­t of incentives to foreign direct investment­s, despite pronouncem­ents to that effect. Most FDI over the years have only come through the incentives given by PEZA, which are mainly dependent on tax-free imported inputs. As a result, most FDIs have little domestic impact. The BOI industries, had they welcomed more basic FDIs in greater quantities, would have enabled more industries that produce basic materials used by other domestic companies. The same policies on joint-venture preference­s in incentives are still in play.

In the meantime, employment is rising in industry among our neighbors much faster than in the country. Recently, an Asian Developmen­t Bank official noted the transfer of many labor-using industries of restructur­ing China to Cambodia, Indonesia, Vietnam and other ASEAN countries. Convenient­ly omitted is the mention of the Philippine­s from the list.

This, unfortunat­ely, is a continuous descriptio­n of the lost opportunit­ies the country has been unable to take full advantage of because of labor market policies that has out-priced Philippine labor through the mechanisms of very extensive restrictiv­e labor laws and government mandated wage policies.

My email is: gpsicat@gmail.com. Visit this site for more informatio­n, feedback and commentary: http://econ.upd.edu.ph/gpsicat/

 ??  ?? CROSSROADS Toward Philippine Economic and Social Progress
CROSSROADS Toward Philippine Economic and Social Progress

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Philippines