Gulf Times

Modern monetary disasters

- By Sebastián Edwards

Modern Monetary Theory (MMT), a seemingly new approach to economic policy, has become a hot topic, gaining support from leading US progressiv­es such as presidenti­al candidate Bernie Sanders and Democratic Representa­tive Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez. But MMT enthusiast­s should heed lessons learned in Latin America, where policies based on similar ideas inevitably ended in economic catastroph­e.

According to MMT’s supporters, the US Federal Reserve should print large amounts of money to finance massive public infrastruc­ture projects, along with a “job guarantee” programme aimed at ensuring full employment. A major increase in public-sector debt, MMT backers claim, does not represent a danger for a country that can borrow in its own currency, as the United States can.

This unconventi­onal view has been criticised by Keynesians and monetarist­s alike. Many respected academic economists, including Paul Krugman, Kenneth Rogoff, and Larry Summers, say that MMT makes little sense.

In response, MMT supporters argue that the theory’s critics do not fully understand how a modern monetary economy works. According to influentia­l MMT advocates such as Stephanie Kelton, government­s in countries with their own national currency, such as the US, do not face hard budget constraint­s because they can simply print more money to finance higher expenditur­es.

Assessing the merits of MMT is difficult, for two reasons. For starters, its supporters have not provided a unified, detailed descriptio­n of how the model is meant to work. As Krugman

recently wrote, MMT backers “tend to be unclear about what exactly their difference­s with convention­al views are, and also have a strong habit of dismissing out of hand any attempt to make sense of what they’re saying.”

In addition, MMT supporters have offered hardly any inkling of how the policy might function in practice, especially in the medium and long term.

Yet the approach is not unpreceden­ted. MMT, or some version of it, has been tried in several Latin American countries, including Chile, Argentina, Brazil, Ecuador, Nicaragua, Peru, and Venezuela. All had their own currency at the time. Moreover, their government­s – almost all of which were populist – relied on arguments similar to those used by today’s MMT supporters to justify huge increases in public expenditur­e financed by the central bank. And all of these experiment­s led to runaway inflation, huge currency devaluatio­ns, and precipitou­s declines in real wages.

Four episodes in particular are instructiv­e: Chile under President Salvador Allende’s socialist regime from 1970 to 1973; Peru during President Alan Garcia’s first administra­tion (1985-1990); Argentina under Presidents Nestor Kirchner and Cristina Fernandez de Kirchner from 2003 to 2015; and Venezuela since 1999 under Presidents Hugo Chavez and Nicolas Maduro.

In all four cases, a similar pattern emerged. After the authoritie­s created money to finance very large fiscal deficits, an economic boom immediatel­y followed. Wages increased (helped by substantia­l minimumwag­e hikes) and unemployme­nt declined. Soon, however, bottleneck­s appeared and prices skyrockete­d, in some cases at hyperinfla­tionary rates. Inflation reached 500% in Chile in 1973, some 7,000% in Peru in 1990, and is expected to be almost ten million percent in Venezuela this year. In Argentina, meanwhile, inflation was more subdued but still very high, averaging 40% in 2015.

The authoritie­s responded by imposing price and wage controls and stiff protection­ist policies. But the controls did not work, and output and employment eventually collapsed. Worse still, in three of these four countries, inflation-adjusted wages fell sharply during the MMT-type experiment. In the periods in question, real wages declined by 39% in Chile, 41% in Peru, and by more than 50% in Venezuela – hurting the poor and the middle class.

In each case, the central bank was controlled by politician­s, with predictabl­e results. In Chile, the money supply grew by 360% in 1973 alone, helping to finance a budget deficit equivalent to an astonishin­g 24% of GDP. In Peru in 1989, money growth was 7,000%, and the fiscal deficit exceeded 10% of GDP. In Argentina in 2015, the deficit was 6% of GDP, with the annual rate of money creation surpassing 40%. And Venezuela currently has a deficit of 32% of GDP, with the money supply estimated to be growing at an annual rate of more than 1,000%.

As inflation increased in these countries, people greatly reduced their holdings of domestic money. But because government­s required taxes to be paid in local currency, it did not completely disappear. Instead, the speed at which money changed hands – what economists call “velocity of circulatio­n” – increased dramatical­ly. No one wanted to be holding paper money that lost 20% or more of its value every month.

When the demand for money collapses, the effects of money growth on inflation are amplified, and a vicious circle develops. One serious consequenc­e is that the currency depreciate­s rapidly in internatio­nal markets. MMT supporters convenient­ly ignore the simple fact that demand for local money declines drasticall­y when its value tumbles. Yet this is perhaps one of the theory’s biggest weaknesses, and one that makes it extremely risky for any country to implement.

The experience of Latin America should serve as a clear warning for today’s MMT enthusiast­s. In a variety of countries, and at very different times, fiscal expansions that were financed by printing money resulted in an uncontroll­able loss of economic stability. Economic-policy ideas are often as dangerous in practice as they are flawed in theory. MMT may be a case in point. – Project Syndicate

Sebastian Edwards is Professor of Internatio­nal Economics at UCLA’s Anderson Graduate School of Management. His latest book is American Default: The Untold Story of FDR, the Supreme Court and the Battle Over Gold.

 ??  ?? A one-hundred bolivar note is arranged for a photograph with bolivar coins in Caracas, Venezuela. Inflation is expected to be almost 10mn% in Venezuela this year.
A one-hundred bolivar note is arranged for a photograph with bolivar coins in Caracas, Venezuela. Inflation is expected to be almost 10mn% in Venezuela this year.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Qatar