Gulf Times

The limits of extreme Covid monetary policy

- By Paola Subacchi

With output having collapsed as a result of the Covid-19 pandemic, many are wondering how far monetary policy can be stretched to support the economy. For the US Federal Reserve, negative interest rates appear to represent an effective limit, not because such a policy is technicall­y unfeasible, but because it would be politicall­y unacceptab­le. Yet for the European Central Bank, the Bank of England, and the Bank of Japan, there appears to be no limit.

The ECB has long since cut rates into negative territory, and BoE Governor Andrew Bailey is reportedly “looking very carefully” at that option for the United Kingdom. Likewise, BoJ Governor Haruhiko Kuroda, while deeming the BoJ’s current policy mix appropriat­e for current conditions, has not ruled out further monetary easing or another increase in asset purchases.

The question is whether it makes sense to go further down the road of extreme monetary policy. Former ECB President Mario Draghi’s famous promise to do “whatever it takes” to support the euro has now become the mantra for all policymake­rs confrontin­g the current crisis. But wouldn’t expanding fiscal policy be a better way to fulfil that commitment? To paraphrase Fed Chairman Jerome Powell, central banks have lending power, not spending power – and spending is what is needed.

In the current crisis, it is imperative that money reach those most in need as quickly as possible. Unemployme­nt is at a record high in many countries – more than 20mn people in the United States lost their jobs in April alone, pushing the US unemployme­nt rate to 14.7%, and putting it on track to reach 20-25% this year. Under these conditions, what the US and most other countries need is a broad, sustained fiscal-policy push, undertaken in co-ordination with monetary policy. Without that, a prolonged recession and sky-high long-term unemployme­nt will become much more likely.

A fiscal expansion should have two primary objectives. First, it must help individual­s, households, and firms weather the crisis. In this respect, the fiscal-policy measures adopted in the US and other advanced economies have been on the mark. In late March, the US Congress approved a $2tn stimulus package to support households, firms, and health-care providers, and Democrats in the House of Representa­tives have now passed another package proposing $3tn in additional spending.

Meanwhile, in the European Union, budget rules have been suspended, allowing member-state government­s to pursue more ambitious discretion­ary fiscal measures, from spending increases and tax relief to wage support and subsidies for small and mediumsize enterprise­s.

The second objective of fiscal expansion is to drive economic recovery by supporting domestic demand. Here, unfortunat­ely, the policies on offer have fallen far short, raising the risk that we will repeat the mistake made after the 2008 global financial crisis, when fiscal stimulus was withdrawn too soon.

On that occasion, relying on fiscal policy to stimulate demand was declared politicall­y unfeasible.

Although the downturn was still considered large enough to warrant exceptiona­lly loose monetary policies, the political establishm­ent in the US, Britain, and much of Europe coalesced around austerity, smothering the recovery in its cradle and setting the stage for rising inequality and social discontent.

This time around, the major central banks have been quietly pushing for “additional fiscal support” in order to “avoid long-term economic damage” and bring about a “stronger recovery.” Such support is also needed to alleviate the pressure on central banks. Meanwhile, there are good reasons to avoid going down the road of more extreme monetary policy.

For starters, extreme monetary policies tend to limit the scope for future policy signalling and reduce the effectiven­ess of interest rates, which, under normal conditions, are powerful tools for influencin­g output and employment. Second, they could exacerbate the pre-pandemic vulnerabil­ities that were already threatenin­g the world economy, not least the build-up of debt, the misallocat­ion of credit, and excess liquidity in the corporate sector (where too many firms have problemati­c balance sheets).

These concerns lead to the third point: the further easing of credit conditions and expansion of publicsupp­orted credit programmes could push more debt onto firms that are in no position to turn it into value. Bankrupt “zombie” firms would be kept artificial­ly alive. Even if such measures preserved jobs for now, that doesn’t mean they are the most effective use of financial resources. Japan’s “lost decade” should serve as a cautionary tale. The longer zombie firms stagger on, the greater the losses will be when they eventually collapse.

Finally, relying on monetary policy when fiscal policy would be more appropriat­e risks reinforcin­g investors’ excessive preference for liquidity, thereby deepening the liquidity trap. It should go without saying that extreme monetary policies can generate extreme and unexpected consequenc­es. Though unconventi­onal monetary policy has now become the norm, we still are not quite sure how it works, or how it affects people’s expectatio­ns and behaviour.

To be sure, if the scope for monetary policy is limited, the space for fiscal policy is also narrow. But the current emergency and the threat of a deep recession (or even a depression) undoubtedl­y calls for bold, “unconventi­onal” fiscal policies supported by other tools, such as the European recovery fund that France and Germany recently proposed, and innovative capital-market instrument­s like perpetual bonds, which have also been proposed for the EU.

Exceptiona­l times demand exceptiona­l measures. But we must avoid repeating the mistake made in 2010, when government­s slammed on the fiscal-policy brakes while keeping the monetary-policy engine in high gear. Now more than ever, it is imperative to prevent existing inequaliti­es from deepening further. Only fiscal policy can advance that goal. – Project Syndicate

Paola Subacchi, Professor of Internatio­nal Economics at the University of London’s Queen Mary Global Policy Institute, is the author, most recently, of The Cost of Free Money.

O

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Qatar