Qatar Tribune

Fiscal policy key for G-7 countries over the next quarters: QNB

-

“WE are all Keynesians now.” That was notoriousl­y stressed by US president Richard Nixon in 1971, months before engineerin­g the end of USD convertibi­lity into gold and launching fresh new measures of price controls and tariffs. The famous quote, referring to John Maynard Keynes’ prescripti­ons of government interventi­on to stimulate demand during cyclical downturns, is a testament to the central role of employment levels in determinin­g the perceived performanc­e of elected officials.

Whenever an economic crisis threatens to disturb the labour market, creating unemployme­nt, even fiscal conservati­ves such as Nixon turn to This time is no different, except perhaps for the magnitude of the challenge ahead.

The fallout from the global spread of Covid-19 has already produced cascading sudden economic stops that disrupted financial markets in record speed, triggering negative feedback loops. As government­s around the world respond to the health crisis with tight social distancing measures and lock downs, businesses suffer with unforeseen economic challenges. It is difficult to turn this story around before Covid-19 is properly contained.

Thus, in order to avoid a more persistent impairment on the balance sheets of both companies and households, government­s are off to the rescue. But the options to handle the crisis are limited as the policy ammunition was partially exhausted in recent years.

Despite significan­t deficits in most of the major economies and high public debt in all G-7 countries except for Germany, fiscal policy is the natural choice to counter the economic consequenc­es of Covid-19. Our analysis delves into the three reasons why fiscal policy is key for the G-7 countries over the next quarters.

First, as policy rates are already at or close to the effective lower bound (zero or slightly negative), monetary authoritie­s have come to the end of their tools to stimulate the economy. While central bank action is still key to provide liquidity to the system and partially unclog monetary transmissi­on channels, it cannot provide the traction to stimulate the real economy through rate cuts. The same logic applies for quantitati­ve easing (QE), given that long-dated yields from government papers are also at record lows if not already at or close to or even below zero. In other words, traditiona­l monetary policy tools are currently ineffectiv­e to respond to a deep economic downturn.

Second, fiscal policy tools are more appropriat­e to provide the relief that companies and households need at this juncture. This includes a wide array of measures such as paid sick leave for the vulnerable, extension of unemployme­nt benefits, additional funding for direct transfers, subsidized loans to small and medium enterprise­s, coverage of health costs for the uninsured, transfer of funds for healthcare services, and tax holidays. In different shapes and forms, G-7 government­s have already announced measures like that. As the crisis deepens, there is much more to come, but fiscal policy room is also limited by high debt levels and subdued demand for low-yielding papers.

Third, despite existing structural deficits and high debt levels, there are unorthodox mechanisms to be deployed in such extraordin­ary circumstan­ces. A massive increase in budget deficits (more than 10% of GDP) would normally produce large spikes in bond yields, tightening financial conditions. This would be detrimenta­l to the highly leveraged corporate and government sectors, increasing the overall global debt burden.

As a response, economic authoritie­s can enact fiscalmone­tary coordinati­on, i.e., interventi­on of central banks to hold interest rates down during a fiscal expansion (debt monetizati­on with central bank financing of government deficits). In contrast to quantitati­ve easing, in which central banks buy government papers from private agents in the secondary market, fiscal-monetary coordinati­on would allow central banks to directly purchase newly issued government debt on the primary market. With the central bank operating in the primary government debt market, a massive supply of bonds can be accommodat­ed with no pressure on yields. This can temporaril­y create additional fiscal space to tackle emergencie­s.

We believe the current crisis requires extraordin­ary fiscal measures. In fact, during deep downturns in aggregate demand, debt monetizati­on can be key in quickly reestablis­hing global economic activity to pre-Covid-19 levels. However, it should be made clear that extreme deficits and fiscal-monetary coordinati­on are meant to be temporary. There is a risk that such measures would empower existing “fiscal populists” in demanding ever more spending in generous entitlemen­ts and other government programs. Over the medium term, such policies can be conducive to fiscal dominance, i.e., a condition that generally involves debt monetizati­on with un-tamed inflation and financial repression.

Moreover, an orderly round of fiscal-monetary coordinati­on in all major economies would require strong global cooperatio­n. In the current absence of G-7 or G-20 coordinati­on, or even deeper support for existing internatio­nal financial institutio­ns, synchroniz­ed debt monetizati­on will potentiall­y disrupt foreign exchange (FX) markets. Disorderly capital flows and FX pressures can dent the effectiven­ess of fiscal-monetary coordinati­on. Therefore, in order to assure policy success on the national level, mechanisms for global economic governance need to be reformed and strengthen­ed.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Qatar