Arab News

The mystery of the missing inflation

- NOURIEL ROUBINI

Because stronger demand means less slack in product and labor markets, the recent growth accelerati­on in the advanced economies would be expected to bring a pickup in inflation.Yet core inflation has fallen in the US this year, and remains stubbornly low in Europe and Japan.

SINCE the summer of 2016, the global economy has been in a period of moderate expansion, with the growth rate accelerati­ng gradually. What has not picked up, at least in the advanced economies, is inflation. The question is why.

In the US, Europe, Japan and other developed economies, the recent growth accelerati­on has been driven by an increase in aggregate demand, a result of continued expansiona­ry monetary and fiscal policies, as well as higher business and consumer confidence. That confidence has been driven by a decline in financial and economic risk, together with the containmen­t of geopolitic­al risks which, as a result, have so far had little impact on economies and markets.

Because stronger demand means less slack in product and labor markets, the recent growth accelerati­on in the advanced economies would be expected to bring a pickup in inflation. Yet core inflation has fallen in the US this year, and remains stubbornly low in Europe and Japan.

This creates a dilemma for major central banks — beginning with the US Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank (ECB) — trying to phase out unconventi­onal monetary policies: They have secured higher growth, but are still not hitting their target of a 2 percent annual inflation rate.

One possible explanatio­n for the mysterious combinatio­n of stronger growth and low inflation is that in addition to stronger aggregate demand, developed economies have been experienci­ng positive supply shocks.

Such shocks may come in many forms. Globalizat­ion keeps cheap goods and services flowing from China and other emerging markets. Weaker unions and workers’ reduced bargaining power have flattened out the Phillips curve, with low structural unemployme­nt producing little wage inflation. Oil and commodity prices are low or declining. And technologi­cal innovation­s, starting with a new Internet revolution, are reducing the costs of goods and services.

Standard economic theory suggests that the correct monetary-policy response to such positive supply shocks depends on their persistenc­e. If a shock is temporary, central banks should not react to it; they should normalize monetary policy, because eventually the shock will wear off naturally and, with tighter product and labor markets, inflation will rise. But if the shock is permanent, central banks should ease monetary conditions, otherwise they will never be able to reach their inflation target.

This is not news to central banks. The Fed has justified its decision to start normalizin­g rates, despite below-target core inflation, by arguing that the inflation-weakening supply-side shocks are temporary. Likewise, the ECB is preparing to taper its bond purchases in 2018, under the assumption that inflation will rise in due course.

If policymake­rs are incorrect in assuming that the positive supply shocks holding down inflation are temporary, policy normalizat­ion may be the wrong approach, and unconventi­onal policies should be sustained for longer. But it may also mean the opposite: If the shocks are permanent or more persistent than expected, normalizat­ion must be pursued even more quickly, because we have already reached a “new normal” for inflation.

This is the view taken by the Bank for Internatio­nal Settlement­s (BIS), which argues that it is time to lower the inflation target from 2 to 0 percent — the rate that can now be expected given permanent supply shocks.

Trying to achieve 2 percent inflation in the context of such shocks, the BIS warns, would lead to excessivel­y easy monetary policies, which would put upward pressure on prices of risk assets and ultimately inflate dangerous bubbles. According to this logic, central banks should normalize policy sooner, and at a faster pace, to prevent another financial crisis.

Most advanced-country central banks do not agree with the BIS. They believe that should asset-price inflation emerge, it can be contained with macro-prudential credit policies rather than monetary policy.

Of course, advanced-country central banks hope such asset inflation will not appear at all, because inflation is being suppressed by temporary supply shocks, and thus will increase as soon as product and labor markets tighten. But faced with the possibilit­y that today’s low inflation may be caused by permanent supply shocks, they are also unwilling to ease more now.

So even though central banks are not willing to give up on their formal 2 percent inflation target, they are willing to prolong the timeline for achieving it, as they have already done time and again, effectivel­y conceding that inflation may stay low for longer.

Otherwise they would need to sustain for much longer their unconventi­onal monetary policies, including quantitati­ve easing and negative policy rates — an approach with which most central banks (with the possible exception of the Bank of Japan) are not comfortabl­e.

This central bank patience risks deanchorin­g inflation expectatio­ns downward. But continuing for much longer with unconventi­onal monetary policies also carries the risk of undesirabl­e assetprice inflation, excessive credit growth and bubbles. As long as uncertaint­y over the causes of low inflation remains, central banks will have to balance these competing risks.

QNouriel Roubini is CEO of Roubini Macro Associates and professor of economics at the Stern School of Business, NYU. Project Syndicate, 2017.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Saudi Arabia