The Edge Singapore

The true toll of the trade war

- BY RAGHURAM G RAJAN

Another day, another attack on trade. Why is it that every dispute — whether over intellectu­al property (IP), immigratio­n, environmen­tal damage or war reparation­s — now produces new threats to trade?

For much of the last century, the US managed and protected the rules-based trading system it created at the end of World War II. That system required a fundamenta­l break from the pre-war environmen­t of mutual suspicion between competing powers. The US urged everyone to see that growth and developmen­t for one country could benefit all countries through increased trade and investment.

Under the new dispensati­on, rules were enacted to constrain selfish behaviour and coercive threats by the economical­ly powerful. The US served as a benevolent hegemon, administer­ing the occasional rap on the knuckles to those acting in bad faith. Meanwhile, the system’s multilater­al institutio­ns, especially the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund, helped countries in dire need of funds, provided they followed the rules.

The US’ power stemmed from its control over votes in multilater­al institutio­ns, both directly and through its influence over countries in the G7. It also had tremendous economic muscle of its own. Importantl­y, though, most countries trusted the US would not misuse its power to further its national interests, at least not excessivel­y. And the US had little reason to betray that trust. No country approached its economic productivi­ty, while its only military rival, the USSR, was largely outside the global trading system.

The expansion of rules-based trade and investment opened up lucrative new markets for US firms. And because it could afford to be magnanimou­s, the US granted some countries access to its markets without demanding the same level of access to theirs.

If policymake­rs from an emerging-market economy expressed concerns about the potential effects of more open trade on some of their workers, economists were quick to reassure them that any local pain would be outweighed by the long-term gains. All they needed to do was redistribu­te the gains from trade to the groups left behind. This would turn out to be easier said than done. Still, in these nascent democracie­s, protests by those left behind were regarded as an acceptable cost, given the overall benefits, and were easily contained. In fact, emerging-market economies became so good at capitalisi­ng on new technologi­es and lower-cost transporta­tion and communicat­ion that they managed to take over large swaths of manufactur­ing from the industrial­ised countries.

Again, trade affected domestic workers unequally, but now moderately educated workers in developed countries — particular­ly small towns — bore the brunt of the pain, while higher-skilled workers in urban service-sector industries flourished.

Unlike in emerging markets, where democracy had not yet sunk deep roots, disaffecti­on among a growing cohort of these countries’ workers could not be ignored. Policymake­rs in advanced economies thus reacted to the backlash against trade in two ways. First, they tried to impose their labour and environmen­tal standards on other countries through trade and financing agreements. Second, they pushed for far stricter enforcemen­t of IP, much of which is owned by Western corporatio­ns.

Neither approach was particular­ly effective at slowing job losses, but it would take something much bigger to upset the old order: the rise of China. Like Japan and the East Asian tigers, China grew on the back of manufactur­ing exports. But, unlike those countries, it is now threatenin­g to compete directly with the West in both services and frontier technologi­es.

Resisting outside pressure, China has adopted labour and environmen­tal standards and expropriat­ed IP according to its own needs. It is now close enough to the technologi­cal frontier in areas such as robotics and artificial intelligen­ce that its own scientists can probably close the gap in the event that it is denied access to inputs it now imports. Most alarming to the developed world, China’s burgeoning tech sector is enhancing its military prowess. And, unlike the Soviet Union, China is fully integrated into the world trading system.

The central premise of the rules-based trading order — that each country’s growth benefits others — is now breaking down. Advanced economies find that the higher regulatory structures and standards that they adopted during their own developmen­t now put them at a competitiv­e disadvanta­ge vis-à-vis differentl­y regulated, relatively poor, but efficient emerging-market countries. And these countries resent external attempts to impose standards they did not choose democratic­ally, such as a high minimum wage or ending the use of coal, especially as today’s rich countries did not have these standards when they were developing.

Equally problemati­c, emerging economies, including China, have delayed opening their domestic markets to the industrial world. Developed country firms are especially eager for unfettered access to the attractive Chinese market, and have been pushing their government­s to secure it for them.

Most problemati­c, though, with China challengin­g the US both economical­ly and militarily, the old hegemon no longer views China’s growth as an unmitigate­d blessing. It has little incentive to benevolent­ly guide the system that enables the emergence of a strategic rival. No wonder the system is collapsing.

Where do we go from here? China can be slowed but cannot be stopped. Instead, a powerful China must see value in new rules, even becoming a guardian of these rules. For that to happen, it must have a role in setting them. Otherwise, the world could break up into two or more mutually suspicious, disconnect­ed blocs, stopping the flows of people, production and finance that link them today. Not only would that be economical­ly calamitous, it would increase misunderst­anding and the possibilit­y of military conflict.

Unfortunat­ely, there can be no going back in time. Once broken, trust cannot be magically restored. China and the US will, one hopes, avoid opening up any new fronts in the trade and technology war, while acknowledg­ing the need for negotiatio­ns. Ideally, they would conclude a temporary bilateral patch-up. Then, all major countries would come together to negotiate a new world order, which accommodat­es multiple powers or blocs rather than a single hegemon, with rules that ensure that everyone — regardless of their political or economic system and state of developmen­t — behaves responsibl­y.

It took a Depression, a World War, and a superpower to make the world see sense the last time. Can this time be different? — Raghuram G Rajan, governor of the Reserve Bank of India from 2013 to 2016, is professor of finance at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business and the author, most recently, of The Third Pillar: How Markets and the State Leave the Community Behind

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Singapore