Business Day

Exploitati­on is about use of informatio­n

- Stuart Theobald

THROUGHOUT history, moneylende­rs have attracted opprobrium — from Shylock’s demand for a “pound of flesh” to the vilificati­on of the banking industry following the subprime crisis.

The current internatio­nal spotlight is on payday lenders such as Wonga, which are facing regulatory and public criticism for their high costs of borrowing.

Locally, unsecured lending has attracted significan­t criticism. From African Bank to the township “mashonisas”, lenders are accused of being unscrupulo­us and exploiting clients.

There is an obvious response to such criticism: lending transactio­ns are voluntary. Clients know what they are getting into, or they can find out.

The availabili­ty of loans is partly about access to finance, a long-time political objective in SA. Lending is often advantageo­us: many businesses wouldn’t be able to open without finance and many individual­s wouldn’t be able to invest in their education. For every borrower who blows the cash on a short-term binge, there may be another who invests it wisely to more than cover the cost of the loan.

With lending, it is difficult to decide where exploitati­on exists and where it doesn’t. That was the message of Shakespear­e’s Merchant of Venice, in which Shylock was both victim and villain.

Karl Marx’s influentia­l definition of exploitati­on is the denial to workers of the surplus their labour generates.

Placing such a definition in the context of lending would have it that lenders unfairly extract a portion of borrowers’ wealth. We are often vague on what is unfair, but high interest rates usually attract outrage. One can easily defend these rates where loans are small and originatio­n costs high. Interest rates need to capture the cost of making the loan as well as the risk of default.

Certain types of loan come with high default rates and are expensive to make, but we still consider them good loans.

However, the defence that lending is a rational economic transactio­n is pretty thin. We know that clients are often not rational. Behavioura­l finance studies show that most people place too much emphasis on immediatel­y satisfying their wants, even though they know they will spend a long time paying for them. In the parlance of behavioura­l finance, we are all prone to “intertempo­ral choice”: we demand instant gratificat­ion without thinking much of the long-term cost; eat, drink and be merry, for tomorrow we may die. That applies just as much to eating a piece of cake as it does to taking out a loan.

Studies have shown such decisions are influenced by everything from the words used in describing the loan, to glucose levels in the decision-maker’s blood. Lenders know people are bad at intertempo­ral choice and can exploit it.

This, to me, is the source of our sense of lending exploitati­on. It is a sense different to Marx’s.

Exploitati­on arises not from the allocation of excess, but from the informatio­n asymmetry held by each party to the deal. The lender knows how to rationally discount money across different periods and the borrower doesn’t.

Lenders can make this worse by heightenin­g the borrower’s irrational­ity, by emphasisin­g the benefit of taking the money immediatel­y, by encouragin­g a decision before the borrower can think more soberly. We call out high interest rates because we think some simply can’t be justified as rational and that the borrower must have been exploited.

This analysis of exploitati­on

Lenders exploit intertempo­ral choice, and this is the source of our sense of lending exploitati­on

has clear policy implicatio­ns.

Behavioura­l economist Richard Thaler and legal scholar Cass Sunstein have written a book entitled Nudge, on how states can intervene to get us to make better decisions. They call their position “libertaria­n paternalis­m” — give people freedom of choice, but intervene with informatio­n and guidance to ensure it’s the right choice.

Applying this to lending, interventi­ons might include making lenders offer standardis­ed products so customers can easily compare. One can slow transactio­ns so customers have time for second thoughts — “cooling-off” periods.

Much can also be done by dictating what informatio­n must be disclosed and what weight to attach to it.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa