Business Day

Ebola shines a light on Africa’s healthcare

- Zaakirah Ismail Ismail is with the economics and economic history department at Rhodes University.

THE recent decision by the National Energy Regulator of SA (Nersa) to grant Eskom an additional tariff hike next year to compensate it for additional costs highlights the need for regulators to avoid passing on overspendi­ng on infrastruc­ture projects to consumers.

Nersa refused to compensate Eskom for cost overruns on power station constructi­on, saying it would allow Eskom to recover only on spending that passed efficiency and prudence tests. This decision is an important warning to state-owned enterprise­s (SOEs) that they must prevent overruns on their spending as they will not automatica­lly be able to recoup it via higher tariffs.

In the 2014-13 national budget, infrastruc­ture spending is estimated to be R847bn over the next three years. Last year’s Budget Review identified an additional R3.6-trillion of infrastruc­ture “mega-projects” under considerat­ion for the next decade.

Public infrastruc­ture projects of this magnitude raise questions about public-sector capacity and funding. An important issue for the regulators of the SOEs tasked with implementi­ng many of the larger projects is how to appropriat­ely price the services delivered to consumers and businesses. An added concern is how to account for the cost overruns that are a regular feature of infrastruc­ture constructi­on.

Since 2006, completed and incomplete infrastruc­ture projects include the World Cup stadiums, the Gautrain, the Gauteng toll roads and the infamous Medupi and Kusile power stations. Each project had a different financing method. No matter the method, the similarity between the projects is that they all had substantia­l project overruns in both time and cost.

It is important to monitor the capital expenditur­e of an SOE when building infrastruc­ture because the higher it is, the higher will be the revenue required to recover constructi­on costs. Regulators are responsibl­e for supervisin­g this process. There are only two ways an SOE can recover revenue: by selling more output and by increasing the prices they charge consumers. Most SOEs will apply to their regulator to allow them to increase revenue by charging higher prices.

An example of increased capital expenditur­e being passed through to consumers due to project overruns is the Transnet New Multi-Product Pipeline. The project completion date was moved from 2010 to last year and the estimated total cost rose from R11.1bn in 2008 to R23.4bn in year 2010. The increased constructi­on costs required Transnet to produce higher revenues to recoup its expenditur­e. Transnet applied to Nersa for an increase in its allowable revenue and thus an increase in the allowed tariff. The higher tariff was passed on to consumers.

Another cause for concern for regulators and consumers is that, once the infrastruc­ture project is commission­ed, funding must come either from consumers, through the user-pays principle, or the taxpayer. The term “user pays” refers to charging customers prices that reflect the costs of providing the goods or services. Producers must charge prices that reflect appropriat­e costs and consumers will benefit from the good/service provided at fair and efficient prices. Alternativ­ely, funding of infrastruc­ture projects comes directly from the government through the budget. This places strain on the government’s balance sheet and creates conflict with competing developmen­t goals. Money from the fiscus is often allocated to more urgent objectives. Therefore, the user-pays principle is deemed the most efficient. However, it becomes problemati­c for regulators, private investors and government­s if users refuse to pay for the infrastruc­ture. An example is the Gauteng e-tolls.

An improvemen­t of Gauteng’s road infrastruc­ture was undertaken by the South African National Roads Agency (Sanral). The government decided the funding would come from tolling rather than the tax base.

Economic theory tell us that as Gauteng’s roads are a pure public good, adequate communicat­ion with users is vital before a decision on financing is made. This allows users to factor future costs into their budgets. If this is not done, users will refuse to pay and funding will be delayed. This becomes problemati­c as delayed funding increases the interest repayments, which eventually gets passed on to consumers.

No referendum was held to see if Gauteng’s road users agreed with tolls as a way to fund the upgrade. Gauteng residents are forced to use the roads without reliable alternativ­es. The subsequent public resistance towards the project is well known. It has negatively affected Sanral’s balance sheet as the revenue expected from the operation of

An important issue for the regulators … is how to price the services delivered to consumers and businesses

the project is not being collected. As a result, Sanral’s global and national ratings were downgraded in February 2012, further increasing the costs of financing its debt.

There are important lessons for regulators and SOEs from SA’s experience. First, given the huge project overruns in infrastruc­ture projects, much greater care must be taken before contractor­s are chosen. Contractor­s must present clear cost and time forecasts based on thorough research. When individual projects are small, engineerin­g, procuremen­t and constructi­on (EPC) contracts should be used to project manage cost overruns and other risks associated with project constructi­on. Under EPC contracts, contractor­s absorb all the risks and failure to meet any contractua­l obligation­s which result in monetary liabilitie­s incurred by the contractor. However, where projects are complex, a cost-plus structure must be used within reasonable limits.

In many cases, project overruns are reported as having been unexpected. This is evaluated only on project completion. The additional capital expenditur­e usually gets passed on to consumers. This should not automatica­lly be allowed. Rather, the relevant regulators should conduct prudence tests of the cost and time delays to verify if the overruns are justified. Only when overruns are justified should the increased costs be passed onto consumers. Regulators should also look to cap overruns at a certain percentage to discourage projects from overrunnin­g. This will create an incentive for both contractor­s and regulated utilities to be more careful in controllin­g costs. If a project overruns beyond the project cap, it must be followed by a prudence test before any extra expenses are passed onto consumers.

Partnershi­ps between regulators and lawenforce­ment bodies are crucial. If a regulator finds that costs of an infrastruc­ture project were artificial­ly inflated, the regulator should report the contractor/utility to the Competitio­n Commission or other law-enforcemen­t bodies. This will ensure consumer protection and create disincenti­ves for contractor­s and utilities to unnecessar­ily inflate costs.

Lastly, it is crucial to the success of the user-pays principle that funding methods are made transparen­t to all parties. This will avoid unnecessar­ily long pay-back periods, which inflate the costs of projects further. This is vital for projects that are pure public goods. The example of the Gauteng e-tolls should be a lesson for all stakeholde­rs involved. Efficiency and transparen­cy are both crucial in managing the financing and funding processes. Research at the inception phase must also be done to show the cost is affordable. Clear channels of communicat­ion must also exist between all stakeholde­rs to take into account the affordabil­ity of the services to consumers.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa