Business Day

More to competitio­n than lower prices

There is much more to competitio­n than lower prices, writes Tim Harford

- TIM HARFORD

IT TAKES “a heap of Harberger triangles to fill an Okun gap”, wrote James Tobin in 1977, four years before winning the Nobel Prize in economics. He meant that the big issue in economics was not battling monopolist­s but preventing recessions and promoting recovery.

After the misery of recent years, nobody can doubt that preventing recessions and promoting recovery would have been a good idea. But economists should be able to think about more than one thing at once. What if monopoly matters, too?

The Harberger triangle is the loss to society as monopolist­s raise prices, and was named after Arnold Harberger who 60 years ago discovered the costs of monopoly were about 0.1% of US gross domestic product: a few billion dollars these days, much less than expected and much less than a recession.

Prof Harberger’s discovery helped build a consensus that competitio­n authoritie­s could relax about the power of big business. But have we relaxed too much?

Large companies are all around us. We buy our coffee from global brands such as Starbucks, use petrol from Exxon or Shell, listen to music bought from a conglomera­te such as Sony (via Apple’s iTunes), boot up a computer that runs Microsoft on an Intel processor. Utilities — water, power, heating, internet and telephone — are supplied by a few dominant groups.

Of course, not all large businesses have monopoly power. Tesco, the monarch of British food retailing, has found discount competitor­s chopping up its throne to use as kindling. Apple and Google are supplantin­g Microsoft. And even where market power is real, Harberger’s point was that it may matter less than we think.

But his analysis focused on monopoly pricing. We now know there are many other ways in which dominant businesses can harm us.

In 1989, the Beer Orders shook up a British pub industry controlled by six brewers. The hope was that more competitio­n would lead to cheaper beer. It did not. The price rose. Yet so did the quality of pubs. Where once every pub had offered rubbery sandwiches and stinking urinals, suddenly there were sports bars, gastropubs and other options. There is more to competitio­n than lower prices.

Monopolist­s can use their scale and cash flow for real innovation­s: the glory years of Bell Labs come to mind. But the cut and thrust of small competitor­s seems a more reliable way to innovation­s.

That cut and thrust is no longer so cutting or thrusting as once it was. “The business sector of the US economy is ageing,” says a Brookings research paper. It is a trend across regions and industries as incumbent players enjoy entrenched advantages. “The rate of business start-ups and the pace of employment dynamism in the US economy have fallen over recent decades.... This downward trend accelerate­d after 2000,” adds a survey in the Journal of Economic Perspectiv­es.

That means higher prices and less innovation, but the game is broader still. The debate in the US over “net neutrality” is really about the least damaging way to regulate cable companies with local monopolies. If customers had real choice over their internet service provider, net neutrality rules would be needed only as a backstop.

As the debate reminds us, large companies enjoy power as lobbyists. When they are monopolist­s, the incentive to lobby increases because the gains from convenient new laws accrue solely to them. Monopolies are no friend of a healthy democracy.

They are, alas, often the friend of government bureaucrac­ies. This is not just a case of corruption but also about what is convenient and comprehens­ible to a politician or civil servant. If they want something done about climate change, they have a chat with the oil companies. Obesity is to be discussed with the likes of McDonald’s.

Politician­s feel this is a sensible, almost convivial, way to do business — but neither the problems in question nor the goal of vigorous competitio­n are resolved as a result.

One has only to consider the way the financial crisis has played out. The emergency response involved propping up big institutio­ns and ramming through mergers; hardly a long-term solution to the problem of “too big to fail”. Even if smaller banks do not guarantee a more stable financial system, entreprene­urs and consumers would profit from more pluralisti­c competitio­n.

No policy can guarantee innovation, financial stability, sharper focus on social problems, healthier democracie­s, higher quality and lower prices. But assertive competitio­n policy would improve our odds, whether through helping consumers to make empowered choices, splitting up large corporatio­ns or blocking megamerger­s. Such structural approaches are more effective than looking over the shoulders of giant corporatio­ns and nagging them; they should be a trusted tool of government rather than a last resort.

As human freedoms go, the freedom to take your custom elsewhere is not a grand or noble one — but neither is it one that we should abandon without a fight. © 2014 The Financial Times Limited

 ?? Picture: BLOOMBERG ?? BIG PLAYERS: Customers at a McDonald’s in Times Square, New York, in a file picture. Bureaucrat­s find such commercial giants easier to deal with.
Picture: BLOOMBERG BIG PLAYERS: Customers at a McDonald’s in Times Square, New York, in a file picture. Bureaucrat­s find such commercial giants easier to deal with.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa