Business Day

Common sense trumps theory

Price wars work in practice even if the logic does not, writes Tim Harford

-

FORTY years ago, German economist Reinhard Selten published a working paper with the title “The chain store paradox”. It was simple and profound and showed a discomfiti­ng disconnect between the fashionabl­e mathematic­al tools known as “game theory” and the recommenda­tions of common sense.

This is the set-up. Imagine a chain store with 20 branches, one in each of 20 small towns. Lacking any competitio­n, these branches charge high prices and are lucrative. In each town, an entreprene­ur is considerin­g opening a rival shop. These 20 local entreprene­urs will, one by one, decide whether to compete against the chain store or sink their capital into something else.

Much depends on the chain store’s response to a competitor. It could be aggressive, ruthlessly slashing prices. That would make life painful for both retailers. The entreprene­ur, committed to a lowmargin business, would wish he or she had invested in something else. Or the chain store could be accommodat­ing, letting prices stay high and sharing a profitable market. So what will happen?

Selten offered two lines of reasoning. One of them is intuitive: the chain store will launch a price war against the first entreprene­ur to set up as a rival. It will lose money in that market but other entreprene­urs will note the bloodbath and steer clear. The reward for giving up one or two cosy local duopolies is that in the other 18 or 19 towns the chain store will remain a monopolist. It will use price wars as a deterrent, and it will work.

The alternativ­e line of reasoning is a matter of inductive logic. Consider the 20th and final town. Deterrence is pointless there, since there are no further entreprene­urs to deter. The chain store may as well eschew a price war and accommodat­e the competitor. Yet if it is obvious that there will be no price war in the 20th town, what about the 19th? If everyone knows there will be no price war in the 20th, what would a price war in the 19th be designed to achieve? Again, deterrence is pointless. But if neither the 20th nor the 19th town will see fierce competitio­n, what is the point of deterrence in the 18th town? The logic rolls back to the beginning of the game; it shows that deterrence is futile and will not be used at any stage.

Selten, an expert in game theory, knew the second scenario was logically watertight. But as a practical matter he found the first “much more convincing”. If he were the chain store, he wrote, he would launch price wars in the hope of deterring later rivals. “I would be very surprised if it failed to work.”

If deterrence works in practice, how to make it work in theory? Selten devoted himself to sharpening up game theory to deal with such paradoxes, and in 1994 he was one of two men to share a Nobel Memorial Prize with John Nash, he of A Beautiful Mind.

One step forward is to add uncertaint­y. Can we be sure the decision will be repeated only 20 times? Can we be sure the competitor­s really understand each other? What if the chain store manager is a thug who loves to crush competitio­n and doesn’t care for his shareholde­rs’ dividends? Deterrence becomes a logical solution as well as an intuitive one.

It was Selten’s chain store paradox that first attracted me to economics, with a heady mixture of logic, psychology and something approachin­g military strategy. And it is a hypothetic­al game with some close parallels today.

Brad Stone’s excellent book The Everything Store: Jeff Bezos and the Age of Amazon, paints Amazon’s founder to be a visionary entreprene­ur, dedicated to serving his customers. But it also reports that Bezos was willing to take big losses in the hope of weakening competitor­s. Zappos, the online shoe retailer, faced competitio­n from an Amazon subsidiary that first offered free shipping and then started paying customers $5 for every pair of shoes they ordered. Quidsi, which ran Diapers.com, was met with a price war from “Amazon Mom”. Insiders told Stone Amazon was losing $1m a day selling nappies. Both Zappos and Quidsi ended up being bought out by Amazon.

When the weapons of war are low prices, consumers benefit at first. But the long term is worrying: a future in which nobody dares to compete with Amazon.

Apple is a striking contrast: the company’s refusal to compete aggressive­ly on price makes it hugely profitable but has also attracted a swarm of competitor­s.

Consider a grimmer parallel. Vladimir Putin’s Russia is the chain store. Georgia, Ukraine and many other former Soviet states or satellites must decide whether to seek ties with the West. In each case Putin must decide whether to accommodat­e or open hostilitie­s. The conflict in Ukraine has been disastrous for Russian interests in the short run but may have bolstered Putin’s personal position. And if his strategy convinces the world that Putin will never share prosperity, his belligeren­ce may yet pay off.

I feel a little guilty comparing Bezos with Putin. My only regret about Bezos’s Amazon is that there aren’t three other companies just like it. I do not feel the same about Putin’s Russia. © The Financial Times Limited 2014

 ?? Picture: BLOOMBERG ?? RUTHLESS: Amazon CEO Jeff Bezos, seen arriving at a conference in Sun Valley, Idaho, in July, has used price wars to devastatin­g effect.
Picture: BLOOMBERG RUTHLESS: Amazon CEO Jeff Bezos, seen arriving at a conference in Sun Valley, Idaho, in July, has used price wars to devastatin­g effect.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa