Business Day

There are arguments for and against reining in Amazon, but emotion is not one of them

- TIM HARFORD

It should not be difficult to love Amazon. To consumers, it offers choice and convenienc­e. Countless internet ventures have relied on its cheap, flexible cloud-computing services to start and scale up.

Amazon makes titans such as Walmart work hard for their revenue, offers a shopping search engine that is Google’s only serious rival, raises the bar for TV networks and sells tablet computers at a price to make Apple loyalists stop and think. Amazon is also giving the US economy what it needs.

Economists Germán Gutiérrez and Thomas Philippon have argued that corporate America is underinves­ting. One reason is that companies are impatientl­y funnelling cash to investors and executives rather than taking a long-term view.

If that is a worrisome state of affairs — and it should be — then Amazon is the shining counterexa­mple. The online retailer’s strategy is driven not by shortterm profit but by investment, innovation and growth. If only there were a few more companies like Amazon, capitalism would be in a happier spot. But there aren’t more companies like it. It’s unique, and an increasing­ly terrifying force in online commerce. Should regulators act? If so, how?

It’s worth first disposing of a bad argument: that Amazon must be challenged because it makes life miserable for its competitor­s, some of which are plucky mom-and-pop operations. Emotionall­y appealing as this might seem, it should not be the business of regulators to prop up such businesses.

Regulators have a tendency to slip into the role of protecting incumbents with surprising ease. Marc Levinson’s history of container shipping, The Box, describes Malcom McLean, the entreprene­ur behind containeri­sation and a risk-taking visionary reminiscen­t of Amazon’s founder, Jeff Bezos. When McLean tried to expand his operations, one of his largest obstacles was the Interstate Commerce Commission in the US, which regulated US railways from 1887 and interstate trucking from 1935.

The Interstate Commerce Commission, writes Levinson, had to approve new routes, commoditie­s and price schedules. When McLean wanted to start a trucking route at a low price, he had to hire lawyers and argue his case at the commission, while his competitor­s protested. “Unfair and destructiv­e,” said the railways. He did not always get his way.

Antitrust authoritie­s should not be in the business of making life easy for incumbents. What, then, should they do? There are two schools of thought. One is to focus on consumers’ interest in quality, variety and price. This has been the approach in US antitrust policy for decades. Since Amazon makes slim profits and charges low prices, it raises few antitrust questions.

The alternativ­e view, which harks back to an earlier era of antitrust during which Standard Oil and later AT&T were broken up, argues that competitio­n is inherently good even if it is hard to quantify a benefit to consumers, and that society should be wary of large or dominant companies even if their behaviour seems benign. The collapse of companies from Lehman Brothers to constructi­on services business Carillion reminds us that size can be a problem when a company is weak as well as when it is strong.

The narrowing in antitrust thinking is described by Lina Khan in a much-read article, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox. Khan berates modern antitrust thinking for its “hostility to false positives”, arguing that it has become incapable of saying anything insightful about modern tech companies.

Unlike Khan, I share modern antitrust’s hostility to false positives; there is a cost to cumbersome and unnecessar­y meddling in a dynamic and rapidly evolving marketplac­e. US President Donald Trump’s history of publicly attacking Bezos is worth pondering too: do we really want the US government to have more discretion as to who is targeted and why?

We should not wish to return to a world in which a plucky new competitor must beg regulators — over the objections of incumbents — for permission to cut prices. We should be grateful that Bezos did not face in the 1990s the regulatory obstacles McLean dodged in the 1950s.

For all this, I am uneasy about Amazon’s apparently unassailab­le position in online retail. Yes, customers are being well served. Yet the company has acquired formidable entrenched advantages, from the informatio­n about customers and the suppliers who sell through it, to the bargaining power it has over delivery companies, to the vast network of warehouses. Those advantages were earned, but they can also be abused.

Antitrust authoritie­s face a difficult balancing act.

Regulate Amazon and you may snuff out the innovation we all say we want more of. Punish it for success and you send a strange message to entreprene­urs and investors. Ignore it and you risk leaving vital services in the hands of an invincible monopolist.

There are no easy options, but it is time to look for a way to split Amazon into two independen­t companies, each with the strength to grow and invest.

If Amazon is such a wonderful company, wouldn’t two Amazons be even better? /©

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa