Business Day

Why exports have not benefited from demand and weaker currency

Policymake­rs and the government need to tackle a number of factors that lead to supply-side constraint­s

- John Stuart Stuart is a Trade Law Centre associate. The working paper this article is based on can be accessed from https://www.tralac.org

In the 1930s, before the era of floating exchange rates, countries would try to gain a competitiv­e advantage for their exports by means of “competitiv­e devaluatio­n”. This practice refers to the deliberate devaluatio­n of a fixed exchange rate vis-avis those of trading partners, to make exports cheaper in the foreign currency. If the exports were relatively undifferen­tiated from competitor­s’, such as agricultur­al produce, this would lead to increased sales relative to other countries’ produce. But even if they were differenti­ated, such as Nikon cameras, making them cheaper would lead to more of them being sold.

Times were tough in the early 1930s, following the Great Depression, but this practice did not improve a country’s situation for long because it usually led to retaliator­y devaluatio­n. The situation is similar to what we now see taking place in the world with US President Donald Trump’s trade war. If country A could devalue its currency, so in turn could country B, and this led to a “race to the bottom”, where in the end no one benefited.

In the modern era, exchange rates are no longer fixed but currencies instead “float” against one another like prices in a market. This does not mean they are completely free to fluctuate — central banks retain some influence over them via monetary policy and they are influenced to some extent by trade policy and exchange control. For this reason, government policy sometimes tackles the need to retain the exchange rate at a competitiv­e level, that is, to prevent it from appreciati­ng to the extent that export sales are negatively affected.

On the other hand, depreciati­on could be encouraged or aided through relaxing monetary policy. SA’s own Industrial Policy Action Plan has in the past specified that a competitiv­e level for the exchange rate is a key part of industrial policy and one that is necessary in the light of limited fiscal space (limited resources with which to directly support industries).

A depreciati­on in the exchange rate will not help competitiv­eness unless it is a “real” depreciati­on, that is, the currency must lose value at a greater rate than relative prices are rising domestical­ly. This is another way of saying that the depreciati­on must not be offset by higher inflation in SA relative to our trading partners. Provided this condition holds, our goods will technicall­y become more competitiv­e in the markets of our trading partners.

Will this competitiv­eness boost actually help exports, however? For a long time this was the case for SA. For total exports, a depreciati­on in the real exchange rate would lead to increased foreign sales, especially our manufactur­ed products. Of course, even a nominal deprecatio­n would increase rand-denominate­d turnover for South African exporters, which is why nominal depreciati­on still helps the share prices of commodity and manufactur­es exporting firms.

However, things changed after the global financial crisis that started in 2008. After this point there was a “disconnect” in the relationsh­ip between the real exchange rate and the volume of exports. This disconnect was not just the fact that exports eventually declined even when the rand depreciate­d, but earlier in the post-2009 period exports actually rose when the rand was appreciati­ng in real terms. So in other words, the relationsh­ip between exports and the exchange rate was broken in both directions.

After about the end of 2011, there was another disconnect in the response of our exports. One of the other drivers of demand for exports, in fact the most important one, is the economic growth in our trading partners’ economies. Although growth slowed in the economies of the developed West after the financial crisis, our “new” trading partners, such as China, South Korea, India and Southern Africa, continued to grow quite strongly. The growth in these economies was more than enough to offset the slowdown in the developed West, and this should have translated into sustained demand for our exports. Yet our exports started to fall after 2000 and as of the end of 2017 had not even recovered to their 2007 levels.

The fact that neither rising demand for our exports nor the competitiv­eness boost of depreciati­on has been able to help our export growth over the past six years is cause for concern. SA is a small, open economy and its economic growth depends on the deepening and widening industrial developmen­t that trade brings. Continued investment, job creation, technology transfer and industrial­isation “upgrading” are all dependent on trade. We cannot afford to have our growth rate stall due to the stagnation of our export industries.

Yet this has happened, even when one factors in the general slowdown in global trade that happened after 2012. The percentage drop in SA’s trade since 2012 is about double the world average, indicating that there are other important factors besides the exchange rate and foreign demand weighing on our export performanc­e.

Various research projects have recently been undertaken to understand what these other factors are. This article is based on a paper that establishe­s that, on a disaggrega­ted industrial basis, the response of exports to the exchange rate and demand varies considerab­ly by sector. Some industries, such as the vehicles and parts sector, fabricated metals products and the fruit export sector, still respond predictabl­y to the exchange rate and foreign demand, albeit with reduced sensitivit­y to any magnitude of depreciati­on.

However, most of the rest of our top 15 export industries do not. Aluminium and aluminium products, coal, and inorganic and organic chemicals products are examples of export sectors that did not respond at all to exchange rate depreciati­on after the global crisis. Our largest export sector, the precious minerals sector — including gold, platinum group metals and diamonds — has also failed to respond at all to exchange rate depreciati­on or foreign demand.

In economics, there is a saying: “The short side of the market rules.” This is another way of saying that whichever of supply or demand most constrains a market will determine the amount of trade in that market. If demand cannot account for the poor performanc­e of SA’s exports, supply must be the culprit. This refers to factors such as:

● Labour market rigidity and uncompetit­iveness;

● Electricit­y supply problems — the inability of Eskom to maintain a stable and cost-effective supply of electricit­y to SA firms;

● Industrial concentrat­ion and uncompetit­ive supply industries;

● Shortages of skilled labour; and

● Policy uncertaint­y.

All of these have been identified in recent research around this issue. What this is saying is that we are facing severe supply-side constraint­s and our ability to return to a healthy level of economic growth depends on their resolution. This will require a co-ordinated approach by policymake­rs and the state. These issues are cross-cutting and involve, inter alia, the stateowned enterprise­s, department­s of labour, education, trade & industry, mineral resources and energy, the presidency and the Competitio­n Commission. In fact, the presidency is now responsibl­e for setting medium-term goals and co-ordinating policy, something that did not happen at all under the previous president.

The breakdown in the relationsh­ip between the exchange rate and our exports is but one indication that SA’s economic engine is broken. A concerted effort is now required to fix it, one indication of which will be that at some point in the future our export industries will again become sensitive to the competitiv­eness boosts of exchange rate depreciati­on.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa