Business Day

Harsh reality has started to expose short-sighted localisati­on measures

Policies reinforce the dominance of incumbents and raise prices while hurting SA exporters’ ability to compete

- Ann Bernstein and Stefan Schirmer ● The authors are with the Centre for Developmen­t & Enterprise.

The idea of shifting demand away from imported goods in favour of those made in SA is an alluring one. Localisati­on policies are seductive: the promise of an upswing in employment and economic growth at a time when both are desperatel­y needed. However, the government is gradually being forced to backtrack from its much-touted localisati­on policies because of their damaging consequenc­es.

Localisati­on policies — preferenti­al procuremen­t, local content requiremen­ts, higher tariffs and import duties — have been central to the government’s 2020 economic recovery plan, building on a deep, long-running strain of protection­ism in SA policy. Yet in August trade, industry & competitio­n minister Ebrahim Patel signalled a retreat when he announced that under bid window 5 of the Renewable Energy Independen­t Power Producer Procuremen­t Programme (REIPPPP), local content requiremen­ts would be reduced from 100% to 35% to help resolve the energy supply crisis.

More back-pedalling came when the department suspended, for 12 months, import duties on chicken products from five countries to ease food inflation. As recently as May, the minister had rebuffed calls for these tariffs to be removed, calling it an “extreme” step that would destroy local jobs. This two-fold retreat from an all-encompassi­ng government commitment to localisati­on is significan­t. It is in effect an admission that localisati­on carries costs too heavy to bear.

In November 2021 the Centre for Developmen­t & Enterprise (CDE) released a report, “The Siren Song of Localisati­on”, arguing against the protection­ism inherent in localisati­on policy. Two leading economists contribute­d to the report.

Prof David Kaplan pointed to the costs of designatin­g goods for local production. “If they have to be designated, it means they were not the buyer’s first choice. There must be a reason for that. Are they more expensive? Are they inferior in some way? There must be a cost to choosing the local product over the imported product, otherwise there would be no point to the localisati­on policy.”

Prof Lawrence Edwards highlighte­d how localisati­on reduces the incentive for firms to keep prices down and to innovate. Protecting local firms from foreign competitio­n and guaranteei­ng them the whole of the local market creates a risk that “you end up supporting very inefficien­t firms”.

In response, Patel asserted in parliament without any evidence that “millions of South Africans joined him” in rejecting the CDE’s report. President Cyril Ramaphosa, meanwhile, “encouraged and welcomed” our work, but insisted that the government’s “localisati­on efforts are on the right path”.

The CDE’s concerns have increasing­ly been echoed by industry leaders. Then RMB CEO James Formby made it clear that localisati­on requiremen­ts are holding back our ability to produce alternativ­e energy. In April, Formby complained about local content rules increasing the cost of wind and solar energy installati­ons. He went on to argue that tariffs on imported steel have a similar effect.

Energy expert Chris Yelland pointed out that under the REIPPPP, “local content designated by the [department] for plant and components ... is proving to be significan­tly unrealisti­c”.

Investec CEO Richard Wainwright similarly warned that in certain sectors “requests for local content are impractica­l”, and Business Leadership SA CEO Busisiwe Mavuso noted that “there is not nearly enough production capacity in SA to meet the requiremen­t for solar energy components”. Imports are urgently needed.

The government’s recent retreat on localisati­on is therefore a welcome developmen­t. It shows that it is possible to influence government policy if the facts are on your side and enough pressure is brought to bear. Sadly, Patel and others still cling to their commitment to localisati­on in spite of its added cost on doing business or providing services. He has said further reductions in local content requiremen­ts would be reviewed only in the event of “further supply challenges”. It is difficult to imagine what more evidence of supply challenges are needed than stage 6 load-shedding.

Critics of the CDE’s report have accused us of ignoring the long-term benefits of localisati­on. They frequently concede that localisati­on raises prices at the time of implementa­tion but maintain that these costs are offset by the local jobs and firms they save from bankruptcy, and the growth benefits they generate over the longer term.

The president, for one, has asserted that “localisati­on is one of several tools to improve the dynamism of the economy, promote investment, develop new markets, transform the economy, promote equitable spatial developmen­t and contribute to the developmen­t of a capable state”. That seems like a lot to expect.

It is not just the government that holds this view. Some captains of industry are strongly committed to the idea that localisati­on will have long-run benefits that outweigh short-term costs. They regard localisati­on as necessary to stop the economy from shrinking. Saving local jobs and firms, they argue, will be followed by “multiplier effects”, thereby generating economic growth.

How should we think about the potential growth effects of localisati­on policies? One possibilit­y is that localisati­on supports “infant industries”. The idea is that anticompet­itive measures give young, smaller firms time, space and market access to build up capabiliti­es and know-how. The worry is that without protection local industries will be outcompete­d on price and/or quality by imports.

This could be a plausible argument if the SA situation was different. In this country the firms receiving state protection are mostly not new entrants trying to find their feet; rather, they are well-entrenched incumbents such as Sasol and ArcelorMit­tal. These firms wield enormous market power in their industries. If after many decades of protection they are still not able to compete with foreign firms, there is no reason to believe they ever will. Quite the reverse: more protection is likely to strengthen the dominance of large, incumbent firms, leading to an even more concentrat­ed economy with low competitio­n.

Requiring firms to purchase more expensive and/or inferior inputs raises the cost of doing business. Ramaphosa has repeatedly talked of the challenge of doing business as a serious growth constraint that will be addressed. He does not appear to see the contradict­ion. Localisati­on measures in effect undermine half-hearted initiative­s to “cut red tape”, serving to put the brakes on economic expansion.

Most importantl­y, raising the costs and lowering the quality of goods has a negative effect on the country’s ability to compete in export markets. Inefficien­t firms with a captive market have little incentive to become more productive and grow. This cuts the country off from a major engine of economic growth: increased production of goods and services for export markets.

Localisati­on cannot, therefore, be redeemed by its benefits. To chart a new course we need many more local firms with the capacity to grow and create jobs. Such firms need large, dynamic markets in which to expand. Markets of that descriptio­n exist almost exclusivel­y outside our borders.

SA should urgently abandon the siren song of localisati­on as a developmen­tal strategy. Instead, we need to focus our efforts on implementi­ng reforms that will make domestic firms more competitiv­e, both at home and in global markets.

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa