Cape Argus

Potholes spell poor public service

Citizens’ actions, unions and toll roads: Saliem Fakir tells how direct action often promotes a review of public choices

-

THE WORST time to impose a tax is when a country’s economic woes are entering a new era of uncertaint­y. Nobody knows exactly what 2012 holds for us, but most believe it is unlikely to be easy for already stretched pockets.

Margaret Thatcher learnt the hard lesson: never push for more taxes when people are already feeling the pinch. After she almost stripped Britain of the last vestiges of a caring economy, she added more salt to the wound with her community poll tax idea in 1991, which met with widespread resistance and her downfall.

Toll roads are generally perceived as an economic burden, as opposed to an elevator of economic prospects.

Toll roads don’t only punish the pockets of individual­s, but also affect the price at which goods and services commute from one part of a country to another. In the end, they are seen as double taxation, both directly and indirectly through the increased costs of goods and services.

Yet roads are an important public good essential for modern economies. It is how we are willing to pay for them that is a source of public consternat­ion.

Citizens – rich and poor alike – pay a fuel levy and general taxes, in one form or another. They would be right in their view that it is the government’s responsibi­lity to look after our roads and pay for them from these taxes and levies.

Of course the government doesn’t have the money to pay for everything because there is obviously more than just roads that need to be built, such as schools, hospitals and other essential infrastruc­ture – from a limited pool of funds.

The government can borrow funds to provide public goods in advance and pay the cost of loans over time, as it collects taxes and sets aside some of these for the payment of new infrastruc­ture. Borrowed money does, however, cost more.

Politician­s and the government in general are entrusted to understand needs and make wise public choices. Sometimes they are better informed than citizens, as they have the opportunit­y to consult a diversity of constituen­cies, have the wherewitha­l to commission robust studies as well as draw on the advice of experts.

At times their choices are good. For instance, nobody disputes that a national health care system is good for all. Even medical aid schemes see the benefit of such a system, despite some opposition, as the medical schemes are also victims of unjustifia­ble pricing from private hospitals and related services.

Nonetheles­s, not all public choices made by the government will be agreeable. And not all of its choices benefit the right constituen­cies. Not all of its choices necessaril­y take into account unintended consequenc­es. And the government itself is not always free from special interests, both inside and outside the bureaucrac­y, which allow a few individual­s to influence public choice against the public interest.

Neverthele­ss, whether a public choice is perceived to be a good or a bad investment depends a lot on how government decision-making is perceived and how well the government works.

Provided it is seen to have deliberate­d sufficient­ly and exhausted all opportunit­ies to resolve disputes with dissatisfi­ed constituen­cies it will have the right to continue as it has, weighing up the benefit to the economy and the majority against the interests of a few.

The only way in which certain public choices can be stopped in their tracks is through recourse to the courts. Often it tends to be the more privileged citizens fighting for their own interests in this manner, unless they have rallied the support of broader constituen­cies and are thus speaking on behalf of them.

As to the case of direct action, this certainly worked against the SA National Roads Agency Limited’s (Sanral) attempt to go ahead with the e-tolling scheme on Gauteng’s roads, which has now been put on hold. Only 10 percent of the province’s estimated two million road users signed up to the e-tolling scheme.

Concerted union, business and other civic pressure was brought to bear on the national minister of transport (who has tried to distance himself from the decision, saying that it was adopted before his time) and the government as a whole.

Whether people will pay for toll roads is also influenced by how well citizens feel the government is doing in managing our roads. Everybody uses roads and we all have experience of the quality of our roads first hand.

In a sense, roads can speak volumes about the state of public services. It is therefore much easier to make synonymous potholes and poor public service in the same breath.

A general deteriorat­ion alludes to either poor management or, as has been shown in some provinces, road repair contracts that go to the wrong people only interested in filling their own pockets.

Toll roads have that added weight of public distrust because they tend to be built and managed via publicpriv­ate partnershi­ps. Often these contracts are not transparen­t because of supposed “commercial confidenti­ality”. So the suspicion grows that there is collusion between state agencies and private vendors in profit-taking, which would leave users deprived of hardearned income.

By and large, given the huge sums involved – in the case of the Gauteng toll roads, about R20 billion – suspicion of profiteeri­ng, lavish lifestyles and corruption are foremost in the public mind. And, as Cosatu points out, surely this money could have been used to improve our public transport system.

There is, as a result, a huge disjunctur­e between what is perceived to be a generous and somewhat healthy tax base, and what is experience­d on the ground as incompeten­ce, mismanagem­ent, corruption and wastage. In the end, the taxpayer has to bear both the burden of the cost of the service as well as misdemeano­urs of state and private contractor­s.

Resistance marks a vote of no confidence in state institutio­ns and citizens’ pressure is an indication that people are not willing to carry the burden of payment of the costs if the status quo remains as it is.

To appease the public, the government will have to restore confidence that it is managing our roads well and that it has considered different options.

Only then will public confidence grow and possibly also the willingnes­s to chip in more for the payment of these goods.

But everybody has to play the same game. We can’t continue having penalties for one party with the other party having the freedom to make decisions without accountabi­lity, as has clearly been the case with the Gauteng e-toll saga.

Saliem Fakir is an independen­t writer based in Cape Town. This article was first published by The South African Civil Society Informatio­n Service (www.sacsis.org.za).

 ?? PICTURE: ZIPHOZONKE LUSHABA ?? TOLL ROAD DEBATE: Public confidence will only grow when the government can show it is able to manage and that it has consulted widely and considered different opinions, the writer argues.
PICTURE: ZIPHOZONKE LUSHABA TOLL ROAD DEBATE: Public confidence will only grow when the government can show it is able to manage and that it has consulted widely and considered different opinions, the writer argues.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa