Cape Argus

Proposed new electoral system passes muster

- DARYL SWANEPOEL

THE Constituti­onal Court, in June 2020, declared the current Electoral Act unconstitu­tional, since it does not allow for independen­t candidates to stand for election to national and provincial legislatur­es. It gave Parliament two years to remedy the defect.

To this end, the Inclusive Society Institute designed a proposed new electoral system that would respond to the court’s ruling, but which would also remedy shortcomin­gs under the existing pure proportion­al model. It needed to:

◆ Accommodat­e independen­t candidates.

◆ Reflect, in general, proportion­ality.

◆ Require no amendments to the Constituti­on.

◆ Be simple for the Independen­t Electoral Commission to implement and for voters to understand.

◆ Promote gender parity, demographi­c and geographic inclusiven­ess, and representa­tivity and improved accountabi­lity to the voter.

In essence, the institute needed to decide between:

◆ A winner-take-all, single-seat constituen­cy approach.

◆ Simplistic proportion­al representa­tion (PR).

◆ A hybrid model that accommodat­ed constituen­cies, with a compensato­ry proportion­al list allowing for overall proportion­ality to be establishe­d.

The single-seat constituen­cy approach was rejected as it would not make it possible for the outcome to reflect proportion­ality. It would also not accommodat­e sufficient diversity.

The simplistic PR model would, in turn, be impractica­l. Imagine the length of a ballot paper should, say, 100 independen­t candidates wish to stand nationally in addition to the 48 existing political parties. It would also not advance geographic representa­tion and would do little to improve representa­tivity and accountabi­lity to the voters.

Thus, the model proposed is a 400seat National Assembly of which 300 are allocated to multi-member constituen­cies (MMCs) each comprising three to seven members. MMCs will be supplement­ed by a proportion­al list of 100 seats, which will be used to ensure overall proportion­ality in terms of the total number of votes cast for parties.

There will be two components to the establishm­ent of the legislatur­e. The first would be representa­tives elected via 66 MMCs. The second component will comprise representa­tives elected via the compensato­ry PR list.

It’s necessary to have at least three members per MMC to promote diversity within each MMC. But too large a number would be counterpro­ductive in terms of promoting geographic representa­tivity, or for bringing representa­tives closer to the electorate.

Accountabi­lity is strengthen­ed when representa­tives are closer to the electorate. Knowing one’s representa­tive, and thereby having greater access to him/her, strengthen­s the voter/representa­tive nexus. Thus, the maximum number of seats per MMC is suggested as seven.

MMCs will be demarcated along current district and metropolit­an municipal lines. Where the number of voters within a district is too few to warrant at least three representa­tives, two or more districts can be added together. Where the number of voters within a metropolit­an council are too many, MMCs can be allocated along sub-council or metropolit­an regional lines. Each vote cast should carry equal weight. Therefore, in determinin­g the borders of the MMCs, the total number of registered voters will be divided by 300 (the number of MMC seats), which results in a quota per seat.

There will be one ballot paper in each MMC, comprising the names of the parties, followed by the names of the independen­t candidates.

Parties will be permitted to nominate a number of candidates equal to the quota size of each MMC plus one. Prior to the election, the parties and the IEC will publicise the names of all candidates so that the electorate will know the incumbents prior to exercising their votes.

The voter will cast a single vote for either the party or the independen­t candidate. Seats will be allocated proportion­ally, based on the number of votes received for each party or independen­t candidate.

Should an independen­t candidate receive enough votes to be elected, he or she will qualify. Party candidates are allocated in order of their appearance on the list for the party in the particular MMC.

Gender parity is promoted by requiring parties to alternate their candidates based on gender, that is man followed by woman, or vice versa, on the ballot paper. This will, however, be difficult to engineer among independen­t candidates, since they represent only themselves.

If independen­t candidates obtain more votes than required for election, the surplus votes are discarded, in that a single individual cannot be more than a single individual.

Thus, only parties will compete for seats on the compensato­ry PR lists. The combined number of votes received by a party, across all MMCs, determine its proportion­al share of the 400 parliament­ary seats. This implies that parties receive an additional proportion of the excess votes forfeited by the independen­ts. Parties could, therefore, be marginally advantaged. This is justified, in that absolute proportion­ality is not possible with the introducti­on of independen­t candidates, and thus a higher reliance will, by necessity, have to be placed on the notion of general proportion­ality. Furthermor­e, it does not come at the expense of the independen­ts, in that it does not diminish the legitimate claim that any one independen­t candidate may have, that is, him or herself represente­d in Parliament. Also, alternativ­e remedies are available. Should the independen­t candidates wish to lay claim to the additional votes cast over and above that required to secure a single seat in the legislatur­e, they could arrange themselves as a group, in reality a party, and register at the IEC as such.

The modelling exercise undertaken by the institute found that the proposed system does not negatively (or positively) impact any party. It shows that the existing power ratios between parties would be maintained. It also shows the geographic spread of seats, continuing to reflect the stronghold­s of the individual parties.

The model being proposed by the institute, therefore, not only gives effect to the constituti­onal requiremen­t of accommodat­ing individual candidates, but it also goes some way to address clear voter desires to be able to hold their representa­tives more accountabl­e. It also does so in a way that the benefits attached to a PR team are not diminished in any way.

The system is fair, it is simple, and it serves the voter. Swanepoel is the CEO of the Inclusive Society Institute. This article is an extract of the institute’s recently published report on a proposed new electoral system for SA. The report can be accessed at https://drive.google.com/file/d/1EeTtWcxS4­rONnXK2Wuf­HTfArsaoDw­kyR/view

 ?? | BRENDAN MAGAAR ?? A WOMAN gets her thumb marked to show that she has voted. South Africa’s electoral system is in need of a thorough overhaul, says the writer. African News Agency (ANA)
| BRENDAN MAGAAR A WOMAN gets her thumb marked to show that she has voted. South Africa’s electoral system is in need of a thorough overhaul, says the writer. African News Agency (ANA)
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa