Mail & Guardian

SA’s poser: Technology vs wages

The fourth industrial revolution and the minimum wage could put a damper on efforts to create a large number of jobs

- Friedrich Kreuser & Neil Rankin

Although technology is making capital cheaper, policies such as the national minimum wage will make labour more expensive. What does this mean for the choices firms make in terms of labour and capital inputs?

Research shows that higher prices for labour will result in a lower demand for it, making job creation more difficult. Along with this, higher wages for low-skilled workers will encourage firms to employ more high-skilled workers and become more skill-intensive.

In South Africa (and globally), a number of trends are changing the relative price of labour. The coming implementa­tion of a national minimum wage will substantia­lly increase the cost of employment, particular­ly of lower-skilled workers. In parallel with this, the fourth industrial revolution is making technology cheaper and more widespread. The effect of both these factors on employment depends crucially on whether firms can move away from using people and towards using machines (capital), or can use them together.

The substituta­bility issue

While capital and labour substituta­bility should be central to the South African employment debate, this matter is often neglected.

At the extreme, if machines and people are perfect substitute­s, they can be swapped to the point where only one is used for production. In such a situation, employment can be created without having to add any further capital.

If they are imperfect substitute­s, or complement­s, then both are required and there is a limit to how much one can be substitute­d for the other. As a result, more capital will be needed if, to create employment, more people are to be hired. And if there are factors limiting capital accumulati­on, this could limit employment creation.

Likewise, the extent to which one type of labour can be substitute­d for another is critical. Can low-skilled workers be hired instead of highskille­d workers, or does one group need the other? And what about semi-skilled workers?

Understand­ing these relationsh­ips is important when crafting sensible policies for South Africa and dealing with its high rates of unemployme­nt, particular­ly among those with lower skills.

The unemployme­nt debate

The narrative often used to explain South Africa’s high unemployme­nt is that those who are unemployed lack the skills firms require. The policy solution is simple, even though implementa­tion may be difficult: provide the requisite skills to those who are unemployed.

Various government initiative­s attempt this solution. Sector Education and Training Authoritie­s (Setas) train workers based on the needs of firms, and learnershi­ps provide subsidised employment and training for new entrants into the job market.

A further constraint is the education system. Work by Stellenbos­ch University’s Research on SocioEcono­mic Policy Group shows how the school system perpetuate­s inequality in the labour market. But educationa­l reform requires political will and capital and, if it were implemente­d today, would probably take a generation to have a real effect.

Consistent­ly missing from the skills narrative is any discussion about the substituta­bility of factors of production and different types of labour, as well as the role prices and wages play in encouragin­g firms to choose capital over labour or one type of worker over another.

Discussion­s on the effect that the relative price of labour has on demand are politicall­y charged, as debates around the national minimum wage have shown. But avoiding the issue may constrain job creation.

A study by Alberto Behar, titled Would Cheaper Capital Replace Labour? in the South African Journal for Economics, considered how the demand for labour is related to wages and the price of other inputs. Using firm-level data from the late 1990s, it finds that capital is a substitute for all occupation­s and that, within labour, unskilled and semiskille­d labour are complement­s, whereas unskilled and skilled labour are substitute­s.

Our research updates that study using data from the World Bank’s Investment Climate Assessment of 2004, a firm-level survey of predominan­tly manufactur­ing firms across the major metropolit­an areas of South Africa. The research estimates a “cost function”, which is a representa­tion of how the cost share of one input is related to the cost of other inputs and output across firms.

This approach estimates how the demand for a specific input, such as labour, changes with its price as well as the prices of other inputs such as capital. This is called the elasticity of substituti­on.

Our results indicate that capital and labour are imperfect substitute­s: an increase in the cost of labour relative to capital is likely to lead to fewer jobs being created.

What does this mean?

In a broad sense, increases in the relative cost of labour — such as the implementa­tion of the national minimum wage — will result in firms employing fewer people and replacing them with machines or other forms of technology. The continuing developmen­t of technology and computing is likely to make laboursavi­ng options cheaper.

This will then make capital cheaper and more productive, and further encourage firms to substitute away from labour. In this environmen­t, job creation will become more difficult.

The results also suggest another explanatio­n for why job creation over the past 20 years has been difficult. Improvemen­ts in macroecono­mic policy, especially monetary policy, have meant that real interest rates — and the price of capital — have fallen since 1994.

Job creation and the policy to facilitate it thus face at least two persistent challenges:

O Falling relative prices for capital, facilitate­d by macroecono­mic policy but also by technologi­cal change, will make capital and technology cheaper; and

O Pressure to increase wages at the lower end will raise the cost of employing people.

Both of these are likely to encourage firms to choose machines over people. Policies for employment creation will need to work twice as hard to compensate for these changing relative prices.

Where do workers stand?

As noted earlier, the research suggests there are different levels of substituta­bility:

• Unskilled and skilled workers are substitute­s as wage increases for one type lead to firms using more of the other type;

• Managers and skilled workers are substitute­s; and

• Unskilled workers and managers are not substitute­s.

If wages for skilled production workers rise, demand for these workers will decrease and firms will hire managers and unskilled workers instead. Likewise, if the cost of hiring managers and unskilled workers rises, demand for skilled workers will increase.

This may help to explain why some parts of organised labour have strong stances on two policies that change the price of lower-skilled workers.

They have opposed the idea of a youth wage subsidy and the implementa­tion of the youth employment tax incentive. This incentive reduces the cost of hiring young, low-paid mostly unskilled workers, encouragin­g firms to employ more of them. Consequent­ly, there would be a reduced demand for skilled workers, the constituen­ts of organised labour.

A national minimum wage, which will increase the price of unskilled labour, is likely to have the opposite effect and encourage substituti­on towards more skilled workers.

Job creation in the future

As technology evolves, job creation is likely to become more difficult, particular­ly for the unskilled workers. Based on the research results, there are at least two areas on which policy can focus.

O Change the price of labour. These results indicate that cheaper labour will result in more employment. Reducing wages is difficult practicall­y, politicall­y and ethically. But there are ways to cut a firm’s employment costs without significan­tly reducing wages.

One way is through a scheme such as the youth employment tax incentive. The limitation of this scheme is that it targets only young workers and new jobs, which may discourage firms from preserving existing jobs.

An alternativ­e approach would be for the government to “top up” the wages of low earners. The United States does this with its earned income tax credit. These top-ups would encourage people to accept work at a lower wage. In South Africa, where high-income earners make up the majority of taxpayers, this scheme would be highly redistribu­tive.

O Change the skills compositio­n of the workforce. The research suggests that higher wages for low-skilled workers encourages firms to employ higher-skilled workers. So: increase the number of skilled workers. Growing this pool of workers has the double benefit of reducing a potential constraint for firms and possibly improving the skills and earning potential of some of the unskilled.

Furthermor­e, the results suggest that policies to create jobs need to respond to the broader trends of the changing nature of work and technology, and the changes in relative costs that result.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa