Mail & Guardian

Search for ways to stop the land slide

Experts say an area-based approach is needed, but district and local government are not on board

-

the Land Reform for Agricultur­al Developmen­t (LRAD) programme. Once the erstwhile moribund department of agricultur­e was incorporat­ed into the land affairs department, the focus was firmly on boosting access of a few aspirant black farmers into the ranks of white commercial farming.

With the election of Jacob Zuma to the presidency, land reform entered what Hall characteri­sed as “capture and confusion”. Introduced by the then land affairs minister, Lulama Xingwana, in 2006 and refined by her successor, Gugile Nkwinti, from 2009, a third change of direction, overlappin­g with LRAD for a few years, was introduced. Known as the Proactive Land Acquisitio­n Strategy, its purpose was ostensibly to enable the state to play a more proactive role in the selection of beneficiar­ies and more productive agricultur­al land (in nodal areas and agricultur­al corridors) with the intent of speeding up land redistribu­tion.

All three approaches were stymied by a combinatio­n of factors, such as high land prices, inappropri­ate beneficiar­y selection, limited access to supplement­ary finance, little postsettle­ment support, and administra­tive incompeten­ce on the part of the department. There was no attempt to integrate land reform into local government spatial planning.

This plethora of overlappin­g policy initiative­s has either not been implemente­d or implemente­d in a halfhearte­d manner, which has left land acquired by the state — sometimes at budget-breaking cost — open to elite capture and exploitati­on by big business.

To answer the question: Where to now for land reform? the organisers of the conference commission­ed three position papers.

Stellenbos­ch professors Nick Vink and Johan Kirsten, coming from a market-led land redistribu­tion approach that minimised the role of the state, argued for a multistake­holder district/local land management committee in each area. Its purpose would be to develop a local vision for agricultur­e, identifyin­g 20% of land under its jurisdicti­on for redistribu­tion. It would approve beneficiar­ies according to agreed criteria and initiate projects, ensuring appropriat­e support for their successful implementa­tion.

Vink and Kirsten pointed out that state-driven land reform has been a failure, diverted by elite capture, and that the productive potential of most transferre­d land has been destroyed. The unresolved land question requires an enhanced national developmen­t plan and “fast-track” redistribu­tion. To achieve this it is necessary to:

O Establish a land reform fund and enable investment in land reform bonds;

O Incentivis­e voluntary contributi­ons of land with empowermen­t recognitio­n;

O Transfer state-owned land; and

O Expropriat­e farms in financial distress or owned by absentee landlords, and unused tax-indebted land.

Taking a contrary position, Mazibuko Jara of Ntinga Ntaba kandoda, a rural movement in the Eastern Cape, argued that the state should be the main institutio­n to acquire land with purchases, expropriat­ion, donations and release of available public land. In his view it is necessary to conduct a review of all pre-transition long-term leases over public land (for example, municipal commonage), and for the state to recognise the rights of people who have occupied land.

New institutio­nal capacities need to be built in the state to plan and provide support. A key policy tool in this process is the municipal integrated developmen­t plans (particular­ly at district level) combined with area-based planning for land and agrarian reform. Another aspect is the mapping of all registered claims for land restitutio­n, as well as the mapping and review of all leases on public land to private users. The mapping of existing agricultur­al production by land-hungry people, farms in debt and under-used land was emphasised.

At the heart of this approach is the developmen­t of a solidarity economy within which land redistribu­tion should contribute to four outcomes: historical redress, wealth (asset) redistribu­tion, decent livelihood­s and improved local economies. The focus of land reform should be unequivoca­lly on the rural poor.

The third position paper, by Michael Aliber of Fort Hare University, proposed that redistribu­tion should be focused largely on smallholde­r land redistribu­tion. He argued that most people who require land need it for housing and small-scale subsistenc­e production in peri-urban areas and therefore these “settlement-oriented beneficiar­ies” should make up 75% of those receiving attention from the state.

This would allow people to have access to multiple livelihood opportunit­ies in semirural and urban contexts. Their eligibilit­y, similar to the urban housing subsidies, should be means-tested. There should be a reprioriti­sing of municipal commonage for small-scale livestock farming.

The second category Aliber highlighte­d is small-scale farmers, who should make up 20% of the total land redistribu­tion spend. To qualify for this programme, farming experience is required. Extension services should include assistance in reaching agricultur­al value chains to market their produce. Jara also emphasised this aspect.

Finally, large-scale farmers should make up 5% of beneficiar­ies and be in a position to make a substantia­l own contributi­on.

All three authors agree that land reform requires decentrali­sed, simplified area-based planning driven by a spatial logic and that it should largely be focused on the poor and landless. But a 2012 Phuhlisani report commission­ed by the department of rural developmen­t and land reform found that formal approval of the area-based planning appeared to be the major stumbling block in the process.

According to the report, the department is dependent on municipal planning and approval processes to enable the area-based planning to be recognised as a sector plan within the integrated developmen­t plan.

Area-based plans for rural developmen­t and land reform are not a legislated output of the integrated developmen­t plan. Without guidelines or regulation­s in terms of the Municipal Systems Act, or alternativ­e regulation binding on all spheres of government, this is likely to remain a major hurdle to negotiate.

The department of rural developmen­t and land reform’s latest annual report (2016-2017) states that it hopes to achieve this integratio­n by 2020. The parlous state of local government is well known. Apart from a shortage of skills, resources and political will, district and local government­s are ambivalent about integratin­g area-based rural developmen­t and land reform plans.

Andries du Toit, the director of Plaas, suggests that the Aliber option has the most chance of succeeding, given current realities. He points out that it presents fairly modest, clearly achievable policies that would work to support existing livelihood strategies, help to ameliorate commodific­ation and create some kind of basis for inclusive growth.

Monty J Roodt is a professor of sociology at Rhodes University

 ??  ?? Unreformed: Redistribu­tion, restitutio­n and tenure, the three pillars of land reform, have failed to redress the inequaliti­es created by colonial and apartheid government­s, perpetuati­ng insecurity, denial of opportunit­ies for income and inequality. Photo: Paul Botes
Unreformed: Redistribu­tion, restitutio­n and tenure, the three pillars of land reform, have failed to redress the inequaliti­es created by colonial and apartheid government­s, perpetuati­ng insecurity, denial of opportunit­ies for income and inequality. Photo: Paul Botes

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa