Sunday Times

From lobbying the state to capturing it

- Thabi Leoka

THE literature on state capture focuses to a great extent on former Soviet countries, but this type of corruption can be found in other parts of the world where politics and business have very close ties and transparen­cy is lacking.

Transparen­cy Internatio­nal defines state capture as “a situation where powerful individual­s, institutio­ns, companies or groups within or outside a country use corruption to shape a nation’s policies, legal environmen­t and economy to benefit their own private interests”.

According to World Bank economists Joel Hellman, Geraint Jones and Daniel Kaufmann, the dominant challenge in designing reform strategies in the initial stages of transition in Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union was to reduce and reorient the state’s role in the economy. The strategies of liberalisa­tion and privatisat­ion were intended to change the way in which the state interacted with firms.

Little attention was paid to the flip side of this relationsh­ip — the ways in which firms exert influence on the state. Such forms of influence had a powerful impact on the pace and direction of reforms, the design of economic and political institutio­ns and, ultimately, on the general quality of governance.

A “capture economy” is one where public officials and politician­s privately sell underprovi­ded public goods and a range of rent-generating advantages to individual firms — at enormous social cost to the overall enterprise sector.

Hellman, Jones and Kaufmann’s research looks at three types of interactio­n between the firm and the state:

Administra­tive corruption: the extent to which firms make illicit private payments to officials to alter the implementa­tion of administra­tive regulation­s on the firm’s activities;

State capture: the extent to which firms make illicit private payments to public officials to influence the formations of laws, rules and regulation­s; and

Influence: the influence firms have on the formation of laws, rules and regulation­s without recourse to illicit and non-transparen­t private payments to public officials.

The key distinctio­n is the source of the rents and the rough distributi­on of those rents in each relationsh­ip.

The most advanced reformers have the lowest levels of state capture, as their progress in liberalisi­ng the economy, strengthen­ing bureaucrat­ic accountabi­lity and promoting political contestabi­lity constrain the extent to which individual firms can capture the state.

Partial reformers, both in terms of their political and economic transition­s, may have made significan­t advances in liberalisa­tion, privatisat­ion and institutio­nal reforms, but their concentrat­ion of political power and limitation­s

State capture is much more damaging than ordinary corruption

on political competitio­n remain a concern.

To understand the economic cost of a captured state, one needs to just read the final report on the financial crisis inquiry commission of 2011, which concludes that the financial industry itself played a key role in weakening regulatory constraint­s on institutio­ns, markets and products.

From 1998 to 2008, the financial sector spent $2.7-billion (R41-billion at today’s rates) in reported federal lobbying expenses.

State capture is much more damaging than ordinary corruption because state institutio­ns fall under the de facto control of persons or networked groups that use the state for their own interests.

It affects the fundamenta­ls of a democratic system.

Leoka is an economist at Argon Asset Management

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa