The Star Early Edition

Is the lack of competitio­n one of the causes of inequality?

Anything that enhances a firm’s ability to exploit consumers can’t be a good thing, writes

-

‘THE NATURE of the market affects distributi­on and hence has much to do with inequality, an obviously pressing issue in this country,” said Judge Dennis Davis at the recently concluded annual competitio­n conference.

His remarks challenged and provoked us on the issue of inequality, in particular, does the increasing concern with inequality call for a competitio­n policy response? How does competitio­n law enforcemen­t square with inequality concerns?

The effect of competitio­n on growth in general can be described in two different ways. One way is to describe the link between competitio­n and the drivers of economic growth. Competitio­n policy promotes growth drivers such as productivi­ty, innovation, investment­s and lower prices.

Competitio­n policy contribute­s to productivi­ty and economic growth through three main channels: (a) competitio­n induces firms to become more efficient to stay ahead of rivals (internal productivi­ty); (b) competitio­n allows high productivi­ty firms to replace laggards (sectoral productivi­ty); and (c) competitio­n pushes firms to invest and innovate (dynamic efficiency).

But I think it is important to recognise that competitio­n law interventi­ons rarely target productivi­ty growth directly; instead they focus on promoting competitio­n itself, often measured by lower prices, entry or other consumer benefits, and in doing so, contribute to productivi­ty growth and thus economic growth overall.

For example, the uncovering of the fertiliser and cement cartels has led to entry in the fertiliser and cement markets. Competitio­n leads to lower prices, including lower input prices, lower costs and more economic activity in follow-on markets.

The other way is to describe the link between competitio­n policy and the challenge of poverty and inequality because the pace of growth is not everything, the pattern of growth also matters.

Desirable effects of competitio­n may be compromise­d by the presence of high levels of poverty and inequality.

Resolving the challenges of unemployme­nt, poverty and inequality is at the core of government initiative­s to foster inclusive economic growth. Inclusive growth is about both the pace and pattern of economic growth.

In his recent thought-provoking book called Professor Tony Atkinson makes the following proposal: “Proposal 2: Public policy should aim at a proper balance of power among stakeholde­rs, and to this end should a) introduce an explicitly distributi­onal dimension into competitio­n policy.”

Some commentato­rs would have you believe that distributi­on does not matter in competitio­n policy, as reflected in the use of the total welfare standard.

I disagree. I consider that such a perspectiv­e is neither descriptiv­ely accurate nor normativel­y appealing.

Not only is such a perspectiv­e troublesom­e from an economic and moral view, it is equally and more importantl­y out of touch with developmen­ts in modern economics (in particular, advances in informatio­n asymmetrie­s and game theory).

Using these developmen­ts in economics, many have rightly argued, including Professor Joseph Stiglitz, that the more successful firms may not only be those who are more able to produce products that consumers love and do so at lower costs; but rather firms that are better able to create and exploit market power, including taking advantage of consumers.

I am persuaded that firms like Telkom, Sasol, SAA, Media24, AMSA, firms involved in the cement cartel, bread cartel, constructi­on cartel and many others would have long lost their dominance were it not for their conduct which created new barriers, reduced competitio­n and enhanced their abilities to exploit customers.

A few would disagree with the assertion that market power is one of the major sources of inequality. The monopolist’s monopoly rents come at the expense of consumers whose well-being decreases as returns from the abuse of market power accrue disproport­ionately to the wealthy. Others have already pointed out that inequality leads to poorer economic performanc­e, including lower growth and more instabilit­y. I agree.

Market power creates barriers to entry, and inequality means fewer people have resources to enter markets.

Even more concerning is the thought that traditiona­lly, strong unions may have appropriat­ed some of the market power rents, but this possibilit­y has weakened today by the decline of active private sector unionisati­on. Some commentato­rs have argued only for a consumer welfare standard for reasons which include the fact that it is readily administra­ble and more likely to engender political support. I find this perspectiv­e incomplete. While the consumer welfare standard helps, it is not justified for reasons based on inequality, and perhaps rightly so, as there are some markets where consumers are wealthy and firms are small or owned by historical­ly disadvanta­ged people. As you probably know, protecting buyers and their consumer surplus provides a poor approximat­ion to preventing wealth transfers to those at the top of the wealth distributi­on.

I agree with the view that overcoming the inequality problem needs a strong embrace of issues of distributi­on. The key question, however, is: Distributi­on to who? Some jurisdicti­ons use the consumer welfare standard but do not consider it distributi­ve.

Fortunatel­y for me, South Africa stands out on this issue in that the pursuit of distributi­ve justice is permissibl­e if not compelled by competitio­n law and its unique responsive­ness to issues of distributi­onal equity and fairness.

Distributi­on is to consumers, workers, small firms, firms owned by historical disadvanta­ged persons and the poor.

While the effect of competitio­n on inequality has not been studied extensivel­y, and has often been assumed to be malign as competitio­n creates winners and losers, Professors William Comanor and Robert Smiley used simple estimates of the prevalence of monopoly profits, together with data on the heritabili­ty of wealth, to suggest that in the US, more than half of the wealth of the richest 2.4 percent of households was ultimately derived from monopoly profits, through inheritanc­e.

In February this year, the World Bank study showed that competitio­n policy in South Africa has brought substantia­l benefits to households, especially the poor.

In my view, competitio­n enforcemen­t should account for inequality concerns by targeting resources towards products purchased by the poor and low income consumers. The commission has already implemente­d a prioritisa­tion policy which led to uncovering cartels in bread (staple food), wheat flour (key input into bread), and maize meal (staple food).

Second, inequality might be addressed in individual cases by adopting creative and innovative remedies targeted primarily to benefit the poor. The commission is already active in not just restoring competitio­n in markets but also crafting remedies with distributi­onal effects to reduce inequality. For example, the Pioneer Foods Settlement Agreement included a discount remedy and a fund to support small businesses.

Let me conclude by making reference to Davis’s final remarks: “In key areas of cartel regulation, abuse of dominance and merger control, a developing jurisprude­nce has taken place which, notwithsta­nding some of the errors that have been committed in the past (not least of all by the Competitio­n Appeal Court), it is possible that both from the perspectiv­e of economic growth and greater equality, competitio­n policy and law can play a significan­t effect.”

I believe therefore that we must also continue to be aggressive in advancing our mission to undertake competitio­n regulation for a growing and inclusive economy. Professor Liberty Mncube is the chief economist at the Competitio­n Commission South Africa, and honorary professor of economics at the University of Stellenbos­ch

 ?? PICTURE: JOHN WOODROOF ?? WEALTH GAP: Nicholas Ndogena begs at a Sandton intersecti­on. It is for the upliftment of people like him, says the writer, that competitio­n must be regulated.
PICTURE: JOHN WOODROOF WEALTH GAP: Nicholas Ndogena begs at a Sandton intersecti­on. It is for the upliftment of people like him, says the writer, that competitio­n must be regulated.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa