Daily Mirror (Sri Lanka)

Fighting for the poor: Strengthen­ing antitrust regulation­s

- BY RAVEEN EKANAYAKE KAUSHALYA ATTYGALLE

In 2013, it was found that brand-name drug manufactur­ers in the United States were paying their competitor­s - generic drug manufactur­ers, to keep their products off the market shelves. In a case that was presented before the Supreme Court, Solvay Pharmaceut­icals had paid a generic drug manufactur­ing company named Actavis close to US $ 30 million each year to delay making a drug that could compete with Solvay’s product, and thus, allowed the brand name company to sell their product at significan­tly higher prices. This “pay-for-delay” agreement deprived consumers of their right to choose and their right to fair pricing of the product. In a country that is trying to make healthcare more accessible to disadvanta­ged communitie­s, such anti-competitiv­e business practices have become a huge impediment to reducing healthcare costs.

This incident is an ideal case in point to highlight the existence of ‘cartels’ and their adverse impact on the poor. Cartels occur when companies stray away from operating within the usual competitiv­e market system and opt to work together instead. These agreements often take place behind closed doors. They serve no legitimate purposes, rather they only serve to rob consumers of the tangible blessings of competitio­n and are viewed as a side-on attack on free market fundamenta­ls. History has elucidated us to the fact that great economic harm and large-scale competitiv­e disadvanta­ges suffered by modern economies are a result of cartel mentality. Cartels inflate prices, restrict supply, inhibit efficiency, and reduce the scope for innovation (Pate 2003).

Types of cartels

Anti-competitiv­e business practice can occur in various forms that affect both buyers and sellers. Price fixing is the most common form of cartel conduct where a group of companies that are considered to be competitor­s agree on the pricing of their goods or services. Another form of cartel occurs when competitor­s agree to share the same customer base, suppliers and even divide certain geographic areas among themselves.

Such cartels even go to the extent of agreeing not to produce the other’s goods and services or expanding to produce the competitor’s goods and services. Bid rigging, or collusive tendering, is another form of anti-competitiv­e cartel behavior that ensures that bids received for a tender notificati­on are submitted in a manner agreed upon by the members of the cartel. Cartels also tend to have restrictio­ns on output which the member companies enter into agreements that limit supply. It is also important to note that cartels can occur both from the seller’s side as well the buyer’s side.

Impact on the poor

While the above mentioned anti-competitiv­e practices can have adverse impacts on consumers in general, the impact of cartels is more severe on the poor. Cartels can impact the poor as both a consumer and a small business owner.

Cartels can affect the poor consumer when price fixing, bid rigging, output restrictio­ns, and shared informatio­n occur in industries producing essential goods and services such as basic food, medicine, fuel, transport, and water. For example, as a result of price fixing, a poor consumer will no longer be able to enjoy the benefits of prices that are based on competitiv­e markets but instead, be forced to reduce their consumptio­n as the good or service may no longer be affordable to them.

Similarly, small and medium enterprise­s are affected by cartels as these small firms face major difficulti­es in entering or even surviving in a market that has a few strong firms operating within a cartel. In a cartelized market, small business owners face many difficulti­es in selling their goods and services at competitiv­e prices as the cartelized firms will be able to dominate market prices. In addition to this, small firms will also have to succumb to higher production costs and lower revenue as they may also have to purchase inputs at higher prices.

While seller cartels are often in the forefront of the discussion on cartels and anticompet­itiveness business practices, buyer cartels could also negatively impact the poor. If a small firm is a supplier to a cartelized market, this will have adverse impacts as the supplier will be forced to sell their products at the price set by the cartel. For example, commoditie­s such as coffee, cotton, tea, tobacco and milk, which are often supplied by small farmers, are known to have buyer cartels that do not allow these farmers to receive the best possible price for their goods.

Thus, effective implementa­tion of competitio­n laws that severely penalize such practices is undoubtedl­y essential to ensure that markets operate in a fair and just environmen­t but above all, these laws are essential to protect poor communitie­s from being further disadvanta­ged.

Anti-trust enforcemen­t

With cartelizat­ion on the rise, government­s across the world are scrambling to regulate markets in the bid to safeguard the interests of consumers, especially the poor. Antitrust legislatio­ns in this lightare viewed as the ‘most effective brake against the cartelizat­ion of industry’ (Arnold 1951).

Almost all countries in the world now have some form of antitrust legislatio­n and have establishe­d dedicated agencies armed to enforce them. The United States (U.S) is at the forefront of the battle against cartelizat­ion; both at home and internatio­nally. It is said to have the toughest and most advanced set of antitrust regulation­s in the world, hence drawing lessons from the U.S would come a long way in assisting emerging economies suchasSriL­ankadrawup­similar frameworks. At the very core of the contempora­ry U.S antitrust legislatio­n framework is the landmark federal statute the ‘Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890’. The Sherman Act prohibits certain business activities that federal government regulators deem to be anticompet­itive, and requires the federal government to investigat­e and pursue trusts, companies, and organizati­ons suspected of being in violation. The Antitrust Division (ATD) of the United States Department of Justice is at the frontlines of antitrust enforcemen­t.

Deterrence and detection

The fundamenta­l objective of any antitrust legislatio­n is deterrence and detection of cartel formation. In pursuit of this objective, an array of tools and sanctions are at the disposal. In the U.S, participat­ion in a cartel is viewed as a property crime, akin to burglary or larceny and thus is dealt with accordingl­y as a criminal offence. In the words of widely respected American jurist, legal theorist and economist, Richard A Posner‘ criminal sanctions are not prices designed to ration the activity; the purpose so far as possible is to extirpate it’.

Thus in addition to civil action for damages (up to treble damages and attorneys’ fees) and class actions, the Antitrust Division, through the criminal justice system are able to prosecute culpable individual­s, who are subject to imprisonme­nt. Under legislatio­n in effect since 2004, corporatio­ns couldbefin­eduptoamax­imum of US$ 100 million under the Sherman Act. Fines could be further extended under a provision of federal law allowing, in the alternativ­e to the statutory fines, a fine equal to either twice the gain from the illegal activity or twice the loss to victims. Individual­s convicted of Sherman Act violations can also be imprisoned for up to ten years.

Compared to other crimes, cartel activity is easily concealabl­e, and cartel participan­ts have a strong interest in concealing their unlawful activity, hence, deterrence alone would not suffice, detection plays a pivotal role. Detecting cartels requires enforcemen­t agencies be armed with powerful tools. As such the U.S antitrust division is vested with the power to carry out grand jury investigat­ions of cartel activity. The division is endowed with powers to obtain search warrants and seize relevant documents. With court order, the Division can record conversati­ons without consent. The division’s criminal investigat­ions are supported by other government agencies, such as the FBI and various offices of inspectors general. Agents from these agencies assist in locating and interviewi­ng persons of interest, executing search warrants, or conducting surveillan­ce.

Detection of cartels through leniency programmes is also a powerful tool in the arsenal of most antitrust enforcemen­t agencies. Leniency programmes affect deterrence in a number of ways; firstly they directly increase the expected probabilit­y of being detected. Secondly, leniency programmes have a destabiliz­ing effect on potential cartels because the first participan­t to apply for leniency can escape sanctions that are then imposed on the other cartel participan­ts. Thirdly, through participat­ing corporatio­ns pro- vides access to evidence that otherwise might be unavailabl­e (e.g., documents and witnesses located outside the United States).

Whilst leniency programmes across the globe have been instrument­al in assisting enforcemen­t agencies detect cartels, they have inherent limitation­s owing to their narrow focus on those at the very heart of cartels. They fail to incentiviz­e people who are aware of but not complicate­d by cartel operations, they provide no protection for those whistleblo­wers that are at the periphery of a cartel hence much activity goes unreported. In response to these limitation­s, the past decade has witnessed four jurisdicti­ons namely, South Korea, the United Kingdom, Hungary and Pakistan expanding their leniency programmes to incorporat­e antitrust informant or whistleblo­wer reward programmes which incentive whistle blowing through monetary rewards and protect whistleblo­wer’s identity from disclosure. The reward program administer­ed by the UK office of Fair Trading offers monetary rewards up to US$ 157,000 depending on the value of informatio­n, harm to the economy and consumers and the effort and risk involve in providing the informatio­n.

Way forward

In Sri Lanka, antitrust legislatio­n is provided through provisions under clauses 34 and 35 of the Consumer Affairs Authority Act, No.9 of 2003. The Consumer Affairs Authority (CAA) is the sole agency tasked with enforcing these regulation­s.

Antitrust legislatio­n and enforcemen­t is still at its infancy. A collaborat­ive study carried out by the Institute of Policy Studies of Sri Lanka (IPS), the Law and Society Trust and the Consumer Unity and Trust Society back in 2003, shed light on the possibilit­y of cartel mentality prevalent in the cement and shipping industries in Sri Lanka. A decade-on since the publishing of findings, the question still remains, as to whether regulatory authoritie­s have been able to detect such operations and have taken necessary measures to deal with them.

The CAA has been alleged of not being proactive enough, placing too much emphasis on investigat­ion matters relating to pricing and the protection of consumers as opposed to carrying out investigat­ions into the more pertinent area of anti-competitiv­e practices, thereby allowing cartel operations to largely operate unfettered. In this light, a good first step would be to enhance detection measures by way of arming the CAA with corporate leniency programmes and whistleblo­wer rewards schemes details earlier, whilst at the same time strengthen­ing deterrence by way of criminaliz­ing cartel operations. In drawing up such framework Sri Lanka should draw upon lessons/experience­s of other nations such as the US, EU, Australia and Canada which are at the frontlines of the battle against cartels. (The Authors are Research

Assistants at the IPS. The more detailed version with endnotes and references is

available in the IPS Blog ‘Talking Economics’: www.

ips.lk/talkingeco­nomics )

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Sri Lanka