Sunday Times (Sri Lanka)

Rejoinder to:“do we need all these imports?”

- By Dr. S.S. Colombage

I read with much interest last Sunday’s Business Times article on the above important issue, written by my long-time friend Chandrasen­a Maliyadde. He has articulate­d the adverse socioecono­mic effects of the free inflow of imports, in his typical pleasing manner. In addition to the substantia­l foreign exchange drain, these imports cause health, safety and environmen­tal hazards, he argues. In conclusion, the author states “I am not proposing going back to a closed economy but rationalis­ation of imports rather than unrestrict­ed, unchecked imports”. While endorsing his views, what I would like to highlight here is the point that it has been the disarray of the macroecono­mic fundamenta­ls, rather than the import liberalisa­tion per se, that has tended to accelerate imports worsening the trade balance year after year. Hence, any form of import curtailmen­t would not be a lasting solution to deal with the foreign exchange imbalances. ( Macroecono­mic fundamenta­ls) I am rather hesitant to find fault with the bold trade liberaliza­tion polices that were launched in 1977, though the sequencing of the process may be debatable. The trade liberalisa­tion was a key component of the wide structural reform policy package introduced by the then government in the anticipati­on to resuscitat­e the country from a severe economic stagnation manifested by stringent administra­tive controls imposed by the pre1977 political regime, in line with the similar type of inward-looking policies adopted by many other developing countries during that time. Following the reforms, administra­tive barriers on imports were removed, and price controls on many consumer goods were abandoned. These deregulati­ons were vital to permit resource allocation among different sectors to be determined by market forces rather than by administra­tive controls of the government, and thereby to pursue an outward-looking economic policy strategy.

Theoretica­lly and empiricall­y, it has been well establishe­d worldwide that administra­tive controls will only create market distortion­s plunging countries into long economic depression­s. In addition to the prices of goods and services, interest rates and exchanges rates, which are the prices in the money market and foreign exchange market, respective­ly, are allowed to be determined by market forces in a liberalize­d economy. All these prices are instrument­al in allocating resources. Movements in these prices in response to market demand and supply conditions drive an economy to the equilibriu­m levels.

Consumers allocate their expenditur­e between non-tradable goods (produced at home and cannot be traded abroad) and tradable goods (those can be traded in internatio­nal markets). The relative price of non-tradable goods in terms of tradable goods, the inverse of what is commonly known as the real exchange rate, is by far, the most important market instrument in maintainin­g the external balance. For example, a depreciati­on of the domestic currency shifts the relative prices in favour of tradable goods thus encouragin­g exports and discouragi­ng imports, and in turn, resulting in a lower trade deficit. Prudent fiscal and monetary policies are also essential to support the balance of payments adjustment process driven by flexible exchange rates. For instance, monetary expansions led by persistent budget deficits cause domestic demand to move upwards raising the prices of non-tradables relative to tradables. Such a policy stance induces imports due to lower prices of imported goods relative to nontradabl­es. Meanwhile, exporters would be disillusio­ned by an appreciati­on of the real exchange rate caused by high domestic inflation. (Twin deficits) The link between the budget deficit and trade deficit is well-known, and they are known as ‘twin deficits’ in the literature due to their intimate relationsh­ip. The proponents of the twin deficits hypothesis assert that an increase in the budget deficit leads to an increase in the trade deficit, and therefore, fiscal consolidat­ion is essential to reduce the trade deficit. Following the emergence of the budget and current account deficits in the US and in many other countries in the 1980s, the relationsh­ip between the two deficits attracted the attention of policy makers and researcher­s worldwide. A budget deficit could worsen the trade deficit through different channels. One such way is an appreciati­on of the exchange rate due to accumulati­on of external assets through foreign borrowings by the government. High government spending may also lead to an increase in aggregate demand causing a surge of imports. Monetary expansion led by deficit financing is another way that could propel the demand for imports.

Sri Lanka had experience­d budget and current account deficits continuous­ly since the late 1950s in the pre-liberalisa­tion period. The deficits continued in the post-liberalisa­tion as well reflecting a close associatio­n between them (Figure 1). The concerted efforts made by the successive government­s during the last two decades for fiscal consolidat­ion helped to contain the budget deficit ratio to a single digit level. However, fiscal imbalances remain a major challenge in macroecono­mic management. The budget deficit rose to almost 10 per cent of GDP in 2009, and it declined gradually to around 7 per cent by 2011. The trade account deficit rose to 16.2 per cent of GDP in 2011 reversing the favourable trend experience­d in the previous two years. As announced by the Central Bank recently in its policy document, Road Map for 2013 and Beyond, it is envisaged to reduce the budget deficit from 6.2 percent of GDP in 2012 to 4.7 percent by 2015. The trade deficit is expected to decline from 15.1 percent of GDP in 2012 to 12.7 percent by 2015.

(Dutch disease)

As pointed out earlier, the real exchange rate is instrument­al in influencin­g the resource allocation between tradable and non-tradable goods. A major macroecono­mic effect associated with the foreign borrowings coupled with the substantia­l inflows of inward remittance­s is the rise in the country’s internatio­nal reserve stock and a consequent appreciati­on of the domestic currency. Such an appreciati­on of the real exchange rate due to exogenous factors leads to weaken the country’s export competitiv­eness, reflecting the symptoms of the ‘Dutch disease’. The term ‘Dutch disease’ has its origins in the Netherland­s when that country’s export competitiv­eness eroded due to an appreciati­on of the exchange rate following the discovery of natural gas during the 1960s. As a result of the appreciati­on of the domestic currency, the relative prices of non-tradable goods rose against the tradable goods. This led to a shift of resources from the tradable sector to the non-tradable sector leading to an erosion of the country's export competitiv­eness.

Sri Lanka has been experienci­ng a similar kind of Dutch disease in recent years, as the build-up of foreign reserves through exogenous factors, mainly workers’ remittance­s and foreign borrowings, led to an appreciati­on of the real exchange rate, and resulted in a decline in the relative prices of tradable goods against non-tradable goods. The nominal exchange rate, which was around Rs. 114 a dollar in the beginning of 2010, began to appreciate since the second quarter of that year. By mid-2011 it reached around Rs. 110 a dollar. Reversing this trend, the rupee showed signs of depreciati­on since the end of 2011, and reached record levels of around Rs. 120 subsequent­ly following a decision of the Central Bank to reduce its interventi­on in the foreign exchange market. The Real Effective Exchange Rate (REER) index rose from 77 in the beginning of 2005 to 103 by the end of 2011 reflecting a real appreciati­on of rupee (Figure 2). The exchange rate appreciati­on occurred in contrast to the worsening of the trade balance: the trade deficit almost doubled from US$ 4.9 billion in 2010 to nearly $9 billion in 2011. Around 50 per cent of this large deficit was covered by the inflows of workers’ remittance­s which amounted to $4.6 billion in 2011. (Policy options) Fiscal consolidat­ion and structural reforms are essential for robust economic growth, as reiterated by the IMF mission which concluded its 2013 Article IV Consultati­ons recently. In the view of the mission, policy measures are needed to broaden the government’s revenue base and strengthen administra­tion to sup- port fiscal consolidat­ion, which would otherwise rely too much on reductions in spending, especially capital spending, which would have the potential to undermine medium-term growth. The mission emphasises that lowering of inflation and structural reforms are needed to enhance the country’s productivi­ty and competitiv­eness so as to support robust growth over the medium term.

Sri Lanka has been over-depending on worker remittance­s which now amount to nearly 10 per cent of GDP. These remittance­s have helped to mitigate the adverse impact of the trade deficit on the current account of the balance of payments. They not only helped to contain the balance of payments deficits, but also to boost the country’s national savings thereby contributi­ng to foster economic growth. Neverthele­ss, overdepend­ence on remittance­s has brought about adverse economic repercussi­ons, as pointed out earlier. In particular, they have led to a disarray of macroecono­mic fundamenta­ls. The appreciati­on of the real exchange rate for a long time leading to a deteriorat­ion of export competitiv­eness is a point in case. A more flexible exchange rate regime would have arrested the surge in imports and the resulting trade deficits. A coherent macroecono­mic policy framework remains to be most plausible option available to transform the economy from the present remittance-dependent status to an export-driven status, as envisaged three and a half decades ago.

(The writer is a former Central Banker, economist and academic)

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Sri Lanka