Sunday Times (Sri Lanka)

The political roots of falling wage growth

- By Jayati Ghosh, exclusive to the Sunday Times in Sri Lanka

NEW DELHI – It’s now official: Workers around the world are falling behind. The Internatio­nal Labour Organisati­on’s ( ILO) latest Global Wage Report finds that, excluding China, real ( inflation- adjusted) wages grew at an annual rate of just 1.1% in 2017, down from 1.8% in 2016. That is the slowest pace since 2008.

In the advanced G20 economies, average real wages grew by a mere 0.4% in 2017, compared to 1.7% growth in 2015. While real wages were up by 0.7% in the United States (versus 2.2% in 2015), they stagnated in Europe, where small increases in some countries were offset by declines in France, Germany, Italy, and Spain. The slowdown in “success stories” like Germany and the US is particular­ly surprising, given the former’s expanding current- account surpluses and the latter’s falling unemployme­nt and tight labour markets.

In emerging markets, average wage growth in 2017, at 4.3%, was faster than in the advanced G20 economies, but still slower than the previous year ( 4.9%). Asia enjoyed the fastest real wage growth, owing largely to China and a few smaller countries such as Cambodia, Sri Lanka, and Myanmar. But, overall, wage growth in Asian economies mostly decelerate­d in 2017. And in Latin America and Africa, several countries experience­d real- wage declines.

Moreover, the ILO report finds that the gap between wage growth and labour productivi­ty remained wide in 2017. In many countries, labour’s share of national income is still below the levels of the early 1990s.

That raises an obvious question: Given the global output recovery of recent years, why have conditions for workers in most parts of the world not improved commensura­tely?

Neither of the usual suspects, trade and technology, is entirely to blame. To be sure, large labour- surplus economies’ deepening integratio­n into the global market, together with increased reliance on automation and artificial intelligen­ce, has weakened workers’ bargaining power and shifted labour demand into very specific and limited sectors. But these factors alone do not explain the lack of material progress for most workers.

The real reason workers are getting a raw deal is not so much economic as institutio­nal and political. From country to country, legislatio­n and court judgments are increasing­ly trampling on long- recognised labour rights.

For example, government­s focused solely on improving “labour-market flexibilit­y” have pursued policies that privilege employers’ interests over those of workers, not least by undercutti­ng workers’ ability to organise. An obsession with fiscal consolidat­ion and austerity has prevented the kind of social spending that could expand public employ- ment and improve workers’ conditions. And the current regulatory environmen­t increasing­ly allows for large corporatio­ns to wield power without accountabi­lity, resulting in higher monopoly rents and greater bargaining power.

In short, neoliberal­ism’s intellectu­al capture of economic policymaki­ng across a wide range of countries, is resulting in the exclusion of most wage earners from the gains of economic growth. But this was not inevitable. China, after all, has achieved rapid wage growth, and the share of national income accruing to labour is rising, despite the country’s pursuit of trade and rapid labour- displacing technologi­es.

China’s success may vindicate a model advanced by the late Nobel laureate economist W. Arthur Lewis, which explains how employment in new, more productive sectors can absorb surplus labour and push up wages over all. But, more to the point, China has augmented this effect through systematic state policies designed to improve labour conditions.

As a result, the average nominal minimum wage in China nearly doubled between 2011 and 2018, and wages for workers in state- owned enterprise­s rose even faster. At the same time, the government has expanded other forms of social protection­s for workers, all while pursuing industrial policies geared toward boosting innovation and productivi­ty growth, thus moving the country up the global value chain.

True, China’s political economy is unusual. The government’s concern for workers’ wellbeing could simply reflect the Communist Party of China’s need to secure its domestic political position. In that case, it has forged a Faustian social bargain that is typical of East Asian autocracie­s.

Still, if China can buck the trend of declining wage growth, other countries can, too. First, though, economic policymake­rs around the world will have to shake off the neoliberal paradigm, which has left them incapable of imagining alternativ­e policy approaches. As a political project, neoliberal­ism has run its course. If workers are going to partake in the gains of growth once again, government­s will need to start adopting more progressiv­e policy alternativ­es.

Fortunatel­y, the ILO and the United Nations Conference on Trade and Developmen­t have begun to put more sensible policies back on the agenda, as have some politician­s in the US, the United Kingdom, and elsewhere. But ensuring that the economy serves the bulk of society will require a much bigger push across the board.

( Jayati Ghosh is Professor of Economics at Jawaharlal Nehru University in New Delhi, Executive Secretary of Internatio­nal Developmen­t Economics Associates, and a member of the Independen­t Commission for the Reform of Internatio­nal Corporate Taxation.)

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Sri Lanka