Sunday Times (Sri Lanka)

Is the new stagflatio­n policy-proof?

- By Nouriel Roubini and Brunello Rosa (Nouriel Roubini, Professor Emeritus of Economics at New York University’s Stern School of Business, is Chief Economist at Atlas Capital Team while Brunello Rosa, CEO of Rosa & Roubini Associates, is a visiting profess

NEW YORK – The global economy has suffered two large negative supply- side shocks, first from the COVID-19 pandemic and now from Russian President Vladimir Putin’s invasion of Ukraine. The war has further disrupted economic activity and resulted in higher inflation, because its short- term effects on supply and commodity prices have combined with the consequenc­es of excessive monetary and fiscal stimulus across advanced economies, especially the US but also in other advanced economies.

Putting aside the war’s profound long- term geopolitic­al ramificati­ons, the immediate economic impact has come in the form of higher energy, food, and industrial metal prices. This, together with additional disruption­s to global supply chains, has exacerbate­d the stagflatio­nary conditions that emerged during the pandemic.

A stagflatio­nary negative supply shock poses a dilemma for central bankers. Because they care about anchoring inflation expectatio­ns, they need to normalise monetary policy quickly, even though that will lead to a further slowdown and possibly a recession. But because they also care about growth, they need to proceed slowly with policy normalisat­ion, even though that risks de-anchoring inflation expectatio­ns and triggering a wage-price spiral.

Fiscal policymake­rs also face a difficult choice. In the presence of a persistent negative supply shock, increasing transfers or reducing taxes is not optimal, because it prevents private demand from falling in response to the reduction in supply.

Fortunatel­y, the European government­s that are now pursuing higher spending on defense and decarbonis­ation can count these forms of stimulus as investment­s – rather than as current spending – that would reduce supply bottleneck­s over time. Still, any additional spending will increase debt and come on top of the excessive response to the pandemic, which accompanie­d a massive fiscal expansion with monetary accommodat­ion and de facto monetisati­on of the debts incurred.

To be sure, as the pandemic has receded (at least in advanced economies), government­s have embarked on a very gradual fiscal consolidat­ion, and central banks have begun policy-normalisat­ion programmes to rein in price inflation and prevent a de- anchoring of inflation expectatio­ns. But the war in Ukraine has introduced a new complicati­on as stagflatio­nary pressures are now higher.

Fiscal- monetary coordinati­on was the hallmark of the pandemic response. But now, whereas central banks have stuck with their newly hawkish stance, fiscal authoritie­s have enacted easing policies (such as tax credits and reduction in fuel taxes) to soften the blow from surging energy prices. Thus, coordinati­on seems to have given way to a division of labour, with central banks addressing inflation and legislatur­es tackling growth and supply issues.

In principle, most government­s have three economic objectives: Supporting economic activity, ensuring price stability, and keeping long-term interest rates or sovereign spreads in check through persistent monetisati­on of public debt. An additional goal is geopolitic­al: Putin’s invasion must be met with a response that both punishes Russia and deters others from considerin­g similar acts of aggression.

The instrument­s for pursuing these objectives are monetary policy, fiscal policy, and regulatory frameworks. Each is being used, respective­ly, to address inflation, support economic activity, and enforce sanctions. Moreover, until recently, re- investment policies and flight- to- safety capital flows had kept long- term interest rates low by maintainin­g downward pressure on 10-year Treasury and German bond yields. Owing to this confluence of factors, the system has reached a temporary equilibriu­m, with each of the three objectives being partly addressed. But recent market signals – the significan­t rise in long- term rates and intra- euro spreads – suggest that this policy mix will become inadequate, producing new disequilib­ria.

Additional fiscal stimulus and sanctions on Russia may feed inflation, thus partly defeating monetary policymake­rs’ efforts. Moreover, central banks’ drive to tame inflation via higher policy rates will become inconsiste­nt with accommodat ive bal - ance-sheet policies, and this could result in higher longer-term interest rates and sovereign spreads, which are already drifting sharply upwards.

Central banks will have to continue juggling the incompatib­le objectives of taming inflation while also keeping long- term rates ( or intra- eurozone spreads) low through balance- sheet maintenanc­e policies. And all the while, government­s will continue to fuel inflationa­ry pressures with fiscal stimulus and persistent sanctions.

Over time, tighter monetary policies may cause a growth slowdown or outright recession. But another risk is that monetary policy will be constraine­d by the threat of a debt trap. With private and public debt levels at historic highs as a share of GDP, central bankers can take policy normalisat­ion only so far before risking a financial crash in debt and equity markets.

At that point, government­s, under pressure from disgruntle­d citizens, may be tempted to come to the rescue with price and wage caps and administra­tive controls to tame inflation. These measures have proved unsuccessf­ul in the past (causing, for example, rationing) – not least in the stagflatio­nary 1970s – and there is no reason to think that this time would be different. If anything, some government­s would make matters even worse by, say, re- introducin­g automatic indexation mechanisms for salaries and pensions.

In such a scenario, all policymake­rs would realise the limitation­s of their own tools. Central banks would see that their ability to control inflation is circumscri­bed by the need to continue monetising public and private debts. And government­s would see that their ability to maintain sanctions on Russia is constraine­d by the negative impacts on their own economies (in terms of both overall activity and inflation).

There are two possible endgames. Policymake­rs may abandon one of their objectives, leading to higher inflation, lower growth, higher long-term interest rates, or softer sanctions – accompanie­d perhaps by lower equity indices.

Alternativ­ely, policymake­rs may settle for only partly achieving each goal, leading to a suboptimal macro outcome of higher inflation, lower growth, higher long- term rates, and softer sanctions – with lower equity indices and debased fiat currencies then emerging. Either way, households and consumers will feel the pinch, which will have political implicatio­ns down the road.

 ?? ??
 ?? ?? Nouriel Roubini and Brunello Rosa
Nouriel Roubini and Brunello Rosa

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Sri Lanka