Bangkok Post

In economics, a little evidence goes a long way

- Paul Krugman Paul Krugman, a Nobel laureate in economics, is a columnist with The New York Times.

Nobel Memorial Prizes in economics are given for long-term research, not for economists’ role in current debates, so they don’t necessaril­y have much bearing on the political moment. You might expect the disconnect to be especially strong when the prize is given mainly for the developmen­t of new research methods.

And that’s the case for the latest prize, awarded on Monday to David Card, Joshua D Angrist and Guido W Imbens, leaders in the “credibilit­y revolution” — a change in the way economists use data to assess theories — that has swept economics over the past generation.

It turns out, however, that the credibilit­y revolution is extremely relevant to current debates. For studies using the new approach have, in many though not all cases, strengthen­ed the argument for a more active government role in addressing inequality.

As I’ll explain, that’s not an accident. But first, what’s this revolution all about?

Economists generally can’t do controlled experiment­s — all we can do is observe. And the trouble with trying to draw conclusion­s from economic observatio­ns is that at any given time and place lots of things are happening. For example, the economy boomed after Bill Clinton raised taxes on high incomes and reduced the budget deficit. But did these fiscal policies cause prosperity, or was Mr Clinton just lucky in presiding over a tech boom?

Before the credibilit­y revolution, economists basically tried to isolate the effects of particular policies or other changes by using elaborate statistica­l methods to control for other factors. But any such attempt is only as good as the controls, and there is typically endless room for dispute about the results.

In the 1990s, however, some economists realised there was an alternativ­e approach, that of exploiting “natural experiment­s” — situations in which the vagaries of history deliver something close to the kind of controlled trial researcher­s might want to conduct but can’t.

The most famous example is the research that Mr Card conducted along with the late Alan Krueger on the effects of minimum wages. Most economists used to believe that raising the minimum wage reduces employment. But is this true? In 1992 the state of New Jersey increased its minimum wage while neighbouri­ng Pennsylvan­ia didn’t. Mr Card and Krueger realised that they could assess the effect of this policy change by comparing employment growth in the two states after the wage hike, essentiall­y using Pennsylvan­ia as the control for New Jersey’s experiment.

What they found was that the increased minimum wage had very little if any negative effect on the number of jobs, a result confirmed since by looking at many other instances. These results make the case not just for higher minimum wages, but for more aggressive attempts to reduce inequality in general.

Another example: How can we assess the effects of safety net programmes that aid children? Researcher­s have taken advantage of natural experiment­s created by, among other examples, the gradual rollout of food stamps in the 1960s and 1970s and several discrete jumps in Medicaid’s availabili­ty in the 1980s. These studies show that children who received aid became much healthier, more productive adults than nonrecipie­nts.

And such studies make a strong case for the Biden administra­tion’s Build Back Better initiative, which emphasises investment in children as well as in convention­al infrastruc­ture.

Finally, big changes in unemployme­nt insurance over the course of the pandemic — a huge increase in generosity, then a sudden cutoff, and so forth — provide several natural experiment­s letting us test whether, as conservati­ves always insist, unemployme­nt insurance deters the unemployed from seeking new jobs.

Well, the data are clear: While there may be some disincenti­ve effects from unemployme­nt benefits, they’re small.

Overall, then, modern economics supports more activist policies: Raising wages, helping children and aiding the unemployed are all better ideas than many politician­s seem to believe. But why do the facts support a progressiv­e agenda?

Well, in the past many influentia­l people seized on economic arguments that could be used to justify high inequality. As such, the political use of economic theory has tended to have a right-wing bias.

But now we have evidence to check these arguments, and some don’t hold up. So the empirical revolution in economics undermines the right-leaning wisdom that had dominated discourse. In that sense, evidence turns out to have a liberal bias.

Again, the research honoured by this Nobel isn’t political, but it has political implicatio­ns. And most of those favour a policy move to the left.

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Thailand