Bangkok Post

Have we hit the limits to growth?

- MICHAEL JACOBS XHULIA LIKAJ ©2022 PROJECT SYNDICATE Michael Jacobs, Professor of Political Economy at the University of Sheffield, and Xhulia Likaj, economist at Forum New Economy in Berlin, are co-authors of ‘Growth, Degrowth or Post-Growth?’

Fifty years ago this spring, one of the most influentia­l books of the twentieth century was published. Written for the Club of Rome by Donella Meadows and colleagues at MIT, The Limits to Growth used new computer models to forecast an uncontroll­able collapse in the global population and economy if prevailing patterns of environmen­tal resource use and pollution continued. Exponentia­l economic growth could not go on forever; at some point in the next 100 years, it would inevitably run up against Earth’s finite environmen­tal limits.

A half-century later, with a climate and environmen­tal crisis upon us, the debate triggered by Limits has returned with a vengeance.

In 1972, the book came under immediate fire from economists who claimed that its authors failed to understand basic economics. If a resource becomes scarce, its price will rise, they pointed out. Other resources will then be substitute­d for it, and it will be used more efficientl­y. Far from leading to social collapse, economic growth was thus self-correcting — not to mention the only way for countries to develop out of poverty.

So confident were mainstream economists that Limits was wrong that one of them, Julian Simon, made a bet with the environmen­talist Paul R Ehrlich about the price of five metals over the following decade. Mr Ehrlich bet that their prices would rise as they became scarcer, Simon predicted that they would become cheaper as other materials were substitute­d for them. Simon won the bet on all five.

But the scarcity of metals — or even fossil fuels — was never really what Limits was about.

As ecological economists Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen and Herman Daly pointed out, the reason physical limits to growth exist is that the planet’s biosphere cannot grow exponentia­lly. Cut down trees faster than they can grow, and deforestat­ion will result. Pump carbon dioxide into the atmosphere faster than it can be absorbed, and the planet will heat up.

More recent scientific research has shown that, for a range of core life-support systems — including the climate — we are fast approachin­g, or in some cases may now have exceeded, the “planetary boundaries” within which humanity can safely prosper.

Mainstream economists recognise this, of course. But they note that economic growth is measured in terms of national income and output (GDP), and there is not a simple relationsh­ip between these indicators and environmen­tal degradatio­n. Using renewable energy, recycling waste, and shifting consumptio­n from goods to services can make economic growth much less environmen­tally damaging. We can therefore have “green growth”: higher living standards and a healthier environmen­t, too.

Rich countries’ CO² emissions have indeed fallen in recent years, even as their economies have grown. But much of this apparent decoupling of GDP growth from environmen­tal damage has been achieved by transferri­ng emissions to China and other emerging economies. And in other areas — including deforestat­ion, fish stocks, and soil depletion — there has been little or no absolute decoupling.

What must be done to avert it? Only “degrowth”, say authors such as Jason Hickel and Giorgos Kallis, can enable the world to live within its environmen­tal means and leave enough resources for the poorest countries to develop.

Unsurprisi­ngly, the economic debate between advocates of green growth and degrowth is also a political argument between pro- and anti-capitalist ideologies. Partly for this reason, a third position — “post-growth” — has emerged in recent years.

Proponents of post-growth economics criticise both green growthers and degrowther­s for focusing on GDP. Since

‘‘ The reason physical limits to growth exist is that the planet’s biosphere cannot grow exponentia­lly.

GDP does not measure environmen­tal degradatio­n or social well-being, neither growth nor degrowth of it should be a primary economic goal. In a recent report for the OECD, a panel of leading economists argue that economic policy should focus instead on society’s paramount objectives — environmen­tal sustainabi­lity, improved well-being, declining inequality, and greater economic resilience.

Because none of these objectives can any longer be guaranteed by economic growth, policymake­rs need to go “beyond growth” to target them directly. As Kate Raworth, author of Doughnut Economics, puts it, we should be “growth-agnostic”.

A key reason for the rise of post-growth ideas is that advanced economies have in recent years had trouble growing at all. Previously normal 2-3% annual increases in GDP have been largely out of reach, with even modest growth sustained only by ultra-low interest rates and huge injections of central bank money.

Economists puzzle over why this is, but recent economic sluggishne­ss certainly makes it easier to contemplat­e low rates of growth brought on by environmen­tal policy, if that is indeed what would happen. One does not have to be an environmen­talist to recognise the overwhelmi­ng priority of curbing the economy’s destructiv­e impact on Earth’s climate and environmen­t.

The Limits to Growth was widely dismissed a half-century ago.

Had that not happened, we wouldn’t need to be having the debate again today.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Thailand