Gulf News

US consumers, firms need to spend again

Only then can likes of Eurozone, China and Japan get to current account surpluses

- By Martin Wolf

Why is the dollar so strong? It has soared 25 per cent on a real trade-weighted basis in the past four years, evoking memories of ascents in the early 1980s and again at the turn of the millennium. In previous cases, the result was a widening of trade and current account deficits. What might be the outcome this time? The answer to the first is that the US has far stronger demand, relative to potential output, than the other big economies. The answer to the second is that it will impose strong deflationa­ry pressure and weaken demand for US output, making it harder to tighten policy than the Federal Reserve imagines.

As Daniel Alpert of Westwood Capital notes: “No economy is an island.” This realisatio­n is what was missing from the analysis of the current state of the Eurozone offered by Jurgen Stark, a former member of the board of the European Central Bank. He argued: “Germany has reliably pursued a prudent economic policy. While others were living beyond their means, Germany avoided excess.”

Yet income and spending has to add up across the world economy. Some can live within their means only because others do not. The prudent depend on the imprudent.

Moreover, what one saw inside the precrisis Eurozone was the combinatio­n of low interest rates with a burgeoning of crossborde­r net lending. As Michael Pettis of Peking University argues, it is nearly certain that the soaring excess of savings over investment in Germany caused excess borrowing and spending elsewhere.

The global economy is an integrated system. At present, among the most important realities is the chronic weakness of private sector demand relative to potential incomes in important economies.

Imbalances between private income and desired spending are now huge in the Eurozone, China and Japan. These economies would be helped by running far larger current account surpluses. All are running, or are likely to run, monetary and other policies that might bring about just this result.

The counterpar­ts for these surpluses cannot now be emerging and developing countries: they are not creditwort­hy enough. The ideal counterpar­ts are countries that can bear the risks of large net capital inflows. By far the most capable is the US, because of its size and ability to borrow in dollars.

The drivers in each of these three giants are strong. In all three, the result is progressiv­e easing of monetary policy, radically so in Japan and the Eurozone.

In the Eurozone, the “sudden stop” in lending to the vulnerable economies triggered crises and then retrenchme­nt in both private and public sectors. In the absence of any offsetting expansion in the creditor countries, the Eurozone as a whole has struggled to become a bigger Germany. Between 2008 and 2013, the current account of the Eurozone swung from a small deficit to a surplus of 2.8 per cent of gross domestic product.

Today, the monetary policies of the ECB will work if the falling euro helps promote a boom in net exports. It is hard to believe in a sustainabl­e domestic spending boom, given the large debt overhangs in vulnerable countries, the absence of fiscal expansion and the fact that households and businesses in creditor countries are reluctant to spend.

China’s challenge

China faces similar challenges. In the runup to the crisis, it balanced the economy by running a trade surplus that peaked at 9 per cent of GDP in 2007. In the aftermath of the crisis, it replaced lost exports with a huge credit-fuelled investment boom, which saw investment rise to half of GDP — unsustaina­ble in an economy whose rate of growth is falling rapidly. How will China now manage its excess supply of savings without suffering a deep recession? The answers are likely to include a rise in trade surpluses, promoted by a weakening exchange rate.

Finally, there

is Japan. There, the corporate sector is the main source of excess savings. But Japan has been willing to offset the huge financial surplus of the corporate sector with a huge financial deficit in the public sector. Today’s ultra-loose monetary policy will not eliminate the excess savings.

A resurgence in the current account surplus would, however, alleviate the consequenc­es. Again, the strong dollar and weak yen can only help the cause.

In a world in which the private sectors of big economies suffer chronic demand deficiency syndrome, we are sure to see a hunt for such scraps of demand as exist. In its World Economic Outlook of October 2008, the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund analysed the fall in the global imbalances and was inclined to believe that it would last. This may prove too optimistic.

At the very least, US spenders will, once again, have to pull not only their own economy but much of the rest of the world. This time, this is unlikely to work for very long.

It is also going to be quite hard work. The Fed must take due note.

 ??  ??
 ?? Nino José Heredia/
Gulf News ??
Nino José Heredia/ Gulf News

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United Arab Emirates