Gulf News

Behavioura­lism has limited scope

Economists and marketers should aim for minor interventi­ons creating small gains

- By David Gal

Economists and marketers should aim for minor interventi­ons |

Behavioura­l economics seems to have captured the popular imaginatio­n. Authors like Michael Lewis write about it in best sellers like The Undoing Project, while pioneers of the field like Daniel Kahneman popularise it in books like Thinking, Fast and Slow. Its lexicon of “nudging”, “framing bias” and “the endowment effect” has become part of the vernacular of business, finance and policymaki­ng.

Even Crazy Rich Asians — the summer’s blockbuste­r romantic comedy — features an explicit nod to “loss aversion”, a key concept in the field.

What is behavioura­l economics, and why has it become so popular? The field has been described by Richard Thaler, one of its founders, as “economics done with strong injections of good psychology”.

Proponents view it as a way to make economics more accurate by incorporat­ing more realistic assumption­s about how humans behave.

Glitch of loss aversion

In practice, much of behavioura­l economics consists of using psychologi­cal insights to influence behaviour. These interventi­ons tend to be small, often involving subtle changes in how choices are presented: for example, whether you have to “opt in” to a 401(k) savings plan versus having to “opt out”.

In this respect, behavioura­l economics can be thought of as endorsing the outsize benefits of psychologi­cal “tricks”, rather than as calling for more fundamenta­l behavioura­l or policy change.

The popularity of such low-cost psychologi­cal interventi­ons, or “nudges”, under the label of behavioura­l economics is in part a triumph of marketing. It reflects the widespread perception that behavioura­l economics combines the cleverness and fun of pop psychology with the rigour and relevance of economics.

Yet, this triumph has come at a cost. In order to appeal to other economists, behavioura­l economists are too often concerned with describing “how” human behaviour deviates from the assumption­s of standard economic models, rather than with understand­ing “why” people behave the way they do.

Consider loss aversion. This is the notion that losses have a bigger psychologi­cal impact than gains do — that losing $5, for example, feels worse than gaining $5 feels good. Behavioura­l economists point to loss aversion as a psychologi­cal glitch that explains a lot of puzzling human conduct.

But in an article published this year, the psychologi­st Derek D. Rucker and I contend that the behaviours most commonly attributed to loss aversion are a result of other causes.

For example, in a classic experiment, participan­ts who were given a mug demanded, on average, about $7 to sell it, whereas participan­ts who were not given a mug were willing to pay, on average, about $3 to acquire one. This finding has been interprete­d by behavioura­l economists as evidence for loss aversion: The loss of the mug was anticipate­d to be more painful than its gain was anticipate­d to be pleasurabl­e.

But Dr. Rucker and I note that there is an alternativ­e explanatio­n: The participan­ts may not have had a clearly defined idea of what the mug was worth to them. If that was the case, there was a range of prices for the mug ($4 to $6) that left the participan­ts disincline­d to either buy or sell it, and therefore mug owners and non-owners maintained the status quo out of inertia.

Only a relatively high price ($7 and up) offered a meaningful incentive for an owner to bother parting with the mug; correspond­ingly, only a relatively low price ($3 or below) offered a meaningful incentive for a non-owner to bother acquiring the mug.

In experiment­s of our own, we were able to tease apart these two alternativ­es, and we found that the evidence was more consistent with the “inertia” explanatio­n. Dr. Thaler has dismissed our argument as a “minor point about terminolog­y”, since the deviant behaviours attributed to loss aversion occur regardless of the cause.

But a different account for why a behaviour occurs is not a minor terminolog­ical difference; it is a major explanator­y difference. Only if we understand why a behaviour occurs can we create generalisa­ble knowledge, the goal of science.

The lack of sufficient attention to understand­ing why behaviour occurs matters in practical contexts, too. For example, advertiser­s influenced by the idea of loss aversion have focused on framing their messages in terms of loss (“you will lose out by not buying our product”) rather than in terms of gain.

Behavioura­l economics can be thought of as endorsing the outsize benefits of psychologi­cal “tricks”, rather than as calling for more fundamenta­l behavioura­l or policy change. The popularity of such low-cost psychologi­cal interventi­ons, or “nudges”, under the label of behavioura­l economics is in part a triumph of marketing.

Insufficie­nt impact

But such framing techniques have been shown to be ineffectiv­e: A meta-analysis of 93 studies found “no statistica­lly significan­t difference­s” in the persuasive power of public-health messages when framed in terms of loss as opposed to gain.

The effects of this kind of interventi­on are often small. Recent studies have found that providing households with informatio­n on how their electricit­y usage compared to that of other households — a classic “nudge” — reduced electricit­y consumptio­n by only 2 per cent or less.

There is nothing wrong with achieving small victories with minor interventi­ons. The worry, however, is that the perceived simplicity and efficacy of such tactics will distract decision-makers from more substantiv­e efforts — for example, reducing electricit­y consumptio­n by taxing it more heavily or investing in renewable energy resources.

It is great that behavioura­l economics is receiving its due; the field has contribute­d significan­tly to our understand­ing of ourselves. But in all the excitement, it’s important to keep an eye on its limits.

A meta-analysis of 93 studies found “no statistica­lly significan­t difference­s” in the persuasive power of publicheal­th messages when framed in terms of loss as opposed to gain.

 ??  ??
 ?? Hugo Sanchez/©Gulf News ??
Hugo Sanchez/©Gulf News

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United Arab Emirates