Rail (UK)

Extracting maximum value frrom new market approaches

JASON CHAMBERLAI­N, Partner, Asset Finance at global law firm Bryan Cave Leighton Paisner LLP, considers the Department for Transport’s plans for market-led proposals in rail

-

THE Department for Transport has recently turned to the private sector for ideas, because as Secretary of State for Transport Chris Grayling declared: “Government­s do not have a monopoly on good ideas for the railways.”

Against a backdrop of largely stripping Network Rail of responsibi­lity for upgrading the railway, the DfT launched its Rail market-led proposals - Call for Ideas.

At the same time, but ring-fenced from the call for third-party ideas, the DfT has called for specific third-party ideas on much-needed rail access from the south to Heathrow Airport - what it calls the Southern Rail Link to Heathrow (SRLtH).

Separately (yet not), it has pushed out another rail enhancemen­ts initiative - Rail Network Enhancemen­ts Pipeline: A New Approach for Rail Enhancemen­ts - to create a pipeline (the RNEP) down which it will put the rail enhancemen­ts government funds. Sounds as if they need some ideas in the acronym department!

The DfT wants to use the market-led proposals it receives in response to its Call for Ideas to help create some “contestabi­lity”.

Contestabi­lity is something you do with or against or around Network Rail in the delivery of railway infrastruc­ture. In a circle as round as it is unbreakabl­e, the DfT has endorsed Network Rail’s response endorsing the independen­t review Network Rail commission­ed into how third parties compete with NR in delivering railway infrastruc­ture, which Network Rail commission­ed under pressure from the DfT to make NR subject to competitiv­e pressure when delivering railway infrastruc­ture.

And then, apart from all that, government­owned Network Rail declared itself open for business to third-party investment to develop the upgrades it has identified. Perhaps NR understand­s contestabi­lity as being contestabi­lity with the government for ideas and investment.

So, Grayling was right: the Government does not have a monopoly on good ideas, but it certainly seems to have a monopoly on not necessaril­y joined-up ideas that it thinks is a good idea to publish all at once.

But if the public sector is constraine­d in how much it spends improving the railway, the private sector is the only place left to look to fill the gap. And there is obvious value in establishi­ng an enhancemen­ts programme, so that the industry and its supply chain can plan.

The right idea then, but what will be critical to whether anything tangible comes of it will be if the DfT can generate enough market confidence that there is the opportunit­y to realise enhancemen­ts ideas, including to monetise them. That confidence is generated by expectatio­n management of pipeline content, certainty of process, and likelihood of reward.

So, who is in the market to make market-led proposals?

A market-led proposal (MLP) is an “unsolicite­d bid” to enhance the railway (unsolicite­d, that is, if you ignore all the soliciting by the DfT for market-led proposals), which the DfT has not already sent down the RNEP. Anyone not publicly funded can make a market-led proposal.

Proposals have been split into two types: ‘Category 1 MLPs’ and ‘Category 2 MLPs’.

Category 1 MLPs are those which do not require public money, government guarantee or exclusivit­y. You might call them ‘Magic Bean Ideas’, because the idea that there are dormant rail enhancemen­ts projects out there that do not require some form of money, underpinni­ng or exploitati­on rights (or a combinatio­n of those) belongs in a fairy tale.

On the assumption that we won’t be seeing the rail equivalent of a giant beanstalk any time soon, let’s focus on Category 2 MLPs, which means the following:

We are really talking about market-led proposals where promoters are looking for some sort of government support.

Promoters must develop their Category 2 MLPs at their own risk and cost.

At some point a promoter will have to run the gauntlet of the DfT’s governance process.

That process - the so-called ‘ RNEP Framework’ - contains the five stages or gateways that a promoter of a railway enhancemen­t must go through before it will be made (below).

These are what you might call instead the five Ds of Dodgeball - Dodge, Duck, Dive, Dip and Dodge - because the owner of an idea to enhance the railway must do each of these things in order to see that enhancemen­t realised. It looks a bit like an obstacle course. To those familiar with government-led procuremen­t, it probably conjures up images of a ‘tough mudder’ with caged crawls, electric shocks and butter-smeared monkey bars.

Despite A New Approach suggesting that an idea can enter the RNEP at any stage, it still needs a government-endorsed business case and to have passed the decision point for that stage. So, in truth, you probably cannot skip a D - unless you’ve Dodged, Ducked and Dived, you won’t be Dipping.

What’s certain is procuremen­t. The Call for Ideas says “procuremen­t is used to ensure value for money”. So, if you have a market-led proposal, it will be contested to some degree. It’s just that at this point you have no idea to what degree, because the messaging on procuremen­t is completely open-ended.

It will be interestin­g to see what kind of market the DfT has managed to create by imposing a deadline for the submission of market-led proposals (July 31).

We know that HS4Air has been put forward - a proposal to join up Heathrow and Gatwick to both High Speed 1 and 2 by by-passing London (a sort of high-speed M25 railway), an

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United Kingdom