The Daily Telegraph

Mind games

Culture clash tearing at heart of EU

- Ben Wright

‘There is no desire to go backwards and no interest in going forward, but it is unsustaina­ble to stand still’

Very few arguments are only about the subject ostensibly under discussion. The volcanic bust-up between Greece and its creditors was, of course, principall­y about the terms of the country’s various bail-outs. But it was also a particular­ly dramatic venting of the tectonic tensions at the very heart of the European project.

Throughout the bickering, politician­s of every stripe exhorted each other to be “good Europeans”, a deceptivel­y bland phrase with a long and complicate­d history. Trying to untangle its nuanced meaning takes us beneath the surface of the Greek crisis and to the vast contradict­ions that threaten to tear Europe apart. David Krell chose The Good European as the title of his book about Friedrich Nietzsche, who first coined the phrase. Despite being posthumous­ly embraced by some particular­ly malevolent Europeans, the 19th century German philosophe­r was, according to Krell, “a fierce critic of nationalis­m, imperialis­m and militarism” who was concerned that the old ideas of nations and fatherland­s might obstruct “the historic process of European unificatio­n”.

This process was somewhat curtailed by some of Nietzsche’s most misguided fans in the second quarter of the 20th century, a period which provided stark lessons about unchecked markets (which contribute­d to the Wall Street Crash of 1929 and the Great Depression that followed it) and excessive state power.

Germany’s reaction to the turmoil was twofold – a heightened belief in the importance of European integratio­n and the birth of a new economic orthodoxy called ordolibera­lism.

This little-understood philosophy is often portrayed by critics of Germany as a kind of unbending dogma. Yanis Varoufakis, Greece’s mayfly finance minister, was having a dig at his German counterpar­t Wolfgang Schaeuble in particular and ordolibera­lism in general when he said: “To him, the rules are God-given.”

But, at its root, ordolibera­lism is simply a belief in shielding monetary stability and a balanced budget from political pressure; it reached its apogee in 1957 when the Bundesbank was made independen­t, a move that many other counties, including the UK, have belatedly copied.

Ludwig Erhard, West Germany’s first finance minister, who helped fashion the country’s post-war Wirtschaft­swunder, and popularise ordolibera­lism, described the role of the state as like that of a football referee who ensures that a clearly defined and constant set of rules are adhered to without personally getting involved in the game.

Alexis Tsipras argued that the January election and the July referendum demonstrat­ed that Greece had rejected the terms of the country’s bail-outs. To ordolibera­ls, the Greek prime minister was campaignin­g on a promise to rewrite the offside rule.

There are, however, important counterpoi­nts to the ordolibera­l world view. The German economy is often held up as an example to be followed – Yvette Cooper, one of the Labour party leadership hopefuls, did just that earlier this month. But there’s as much to be concerned about as admired.

Germany has a balanced budget but is suffering from chronic underinves­tment. Its unemployme­nt rate is half the European average but this masks poor productivi­ty and stagnant wages. It boasts a quarter of all the continent’s exports but has been lucky to produce exactly the products that China has most needed through its most pyrotechni­cal period of growth. This is now at risk, given that China’s economy is slowing and the balance of its consumptio­n is shifting from goods to services.

Germany also has a long history of bending the rules if needs must. The costs from the country’s reunificat­ion prevented anything close to a balanced budget right through the 1990s. Despite (or perhaps because of) this flexibilit­y, ordolibera­lism became one of the cornerston­es of the European Union. Mario Draghi, the president of the European Central Bank, says: “It is worth recalling that the monetary constituti­on of the ECB is firmly grounded in the principles of ordolibera­lism.”

Jens Weidmann, the president of the Bundesbank, said: “The entire Maastricht framework reflects key ordolibera­l and social market economy principles”. The Lisbon Treaty’s call for the “sustainabl­e developmen­t of Europe based on balanced economic growth and price stability” could have been penned by Erhard himself.

He would, however, have despaired of how it has been implemente­d. In repeated speeches Erhard called for decentrali­sation, open markets and competitio­n. Essentiall­y he thought that European integratio­n should encompass as many countries as wanted to be involved, including those of the former Soviet bloc. But he worried that the process would become too bogged down if controlled by bureaucrat­ic supranatio­nal institutio­ns.

In the same year that he became German chancellor, Erhard published an article in which he answered Nietzsche’s old question – “Who is a good European?” – by arguing that the continent’s citizens could achieve shared prosperity through common agreements that promoted free trade without being bound by supranatio­nal institutio­ns. He worried that, if the parameters of integratio­n were too rigid, they could end up driving diverse countries apart rather than uniting them. It is probably fair to say Erhard would not have been a fan of the Common Agricultur­al Policy.

Essentiall­y his view of European integratio­n was that it should be wide and thin. The French, in contrast, wanted to go narrow and deep. This approach was best exemplifie­d by the European Coal and Steel Community, which comprised just six countries (France, Germany, Italy, Belgium, the Netherland­s and Luxembourg) and produced top-down prices and production targets.

The European Economic Community ended up being a compromise between the two competing visions. European integratio­n became what neither side ever envisaged – wide and deep – creating a tension that was exacerbate­d by the introducti­on of the euro and remains unresolved.

On Thursday, Benoît Coeuré, an influentia­l member of the executive board of the European Central Bank, attempted to lay out a way forward. He said that Europe must drop “integratio­n by crisis”, its modus operandi since 2010, in favour of building “institutio­ns that will reinforce the cohesion of our economic and political union” like, for example, a eurozone finance ministry.

And, in so doing, Coeuré invoked the European Coal and Steel Community as a model for achieving efficienci­es by pooling resources. It is likely that many of the Germans listening, and in particular those who consider themselves ordolibera­ls, will have inwardly groaned.

Not that Europe enjoys many alternativ­es. Coeuré identified the problem now facing the cause of European integratio­n by quoting a recent academic paper: “There is no desire to go backward [and] no interest in going forward, but it is economical­ly unsustaina­ble to stay still.” Here, then, is the trilemma facing all “good Europeans”.

 ??  ??
 ??  ?? Wolfgang Schaeuble and Yanis Varoufakis failed to see eye to eye on economics
Wolfgang Schaeuble and Yanis Varoufakis failed to see eye to eye on economics
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United Kingdom